Abstract
Purpose
The purpose of this study is to provide new insights into the relationship between fiscal policy and total factor productivity (TFP) while accounting for several economic and econometric issues of the phenomenon like non-stationarity, fiscal feedback effects, persistence in productivity, country heterogeneity and unobserved global shocks and local spillovers affecting heterogeneously the countries in the sample.
Design/methodology/approach
The paper is empirical. It builds an Error Correction Model (ECM) specification within a dynamic heterogeneous framework with common correlated effects and models both reverse causality and feedback effects.
Findings
The results of this study highlight some new findings relative to the existing related literature. The outcomes suggest some relevant evidence at both the academic and policy levels: (1) the causal effects going from fiscal deficit/surplus to TFP are heterogeneous across countries; (2) the effects depend on the time horizon considered; (3) the long-run dynamics of TFP are positively impacted by improvements in fiscal budget, but only if the austerity measures do not exert slowdowns in aggregate growth.
Originality/value
The main originality of this study is methodological, with possible extensions to related phenomena. Relative to the existing literature, the gains of this study rely on the way econometric techniques, recently proposed in the literature, are adapted to the economic relationship of interest. The endogeneity due to the existence of reverse causality is modelled without implying relevant performance losses of the models. Moreover, this is the first article that questions whether the effects of fiscal budget on productivity depend on the impact of the former on aggregate output growth, thus emphasising the importance of the quality of fiscal adjustments.
Keywords
Citation
Carvelli, G. (2024), "Fiscal adjustments and TFP dynamics: addressing reverse causality within a heterogeneous panel framework with global shocks", Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 51 No. 9, pp. 112-136. https://doi.org/10.1108/JES-08-2023-0447
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2023, Gianni Carvelli
License
Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
The past two decades have been characterised by four major global economic disruptions, i.e. the 2007 global financial crisis, the 2011 European sovereign debt crisis, the 2020 Covid-19 pandemic and the 2022 Russian invasion of Ukraine. These events have stimulated, especially in Europe and the US, the debate on the role of economic policy and the real impacts of fiscal austerity/expansion. Although fiscal responses and their effects have been heterogeneous across time and countries (Afonso and Aubyn, 2010; Calderón et al., 2015; Owusu et al., 2023), the years following the Covid-19 pandemic have been dominated by massive government interventions to stimulate economic activity and mitigate social inequalities associated with the crises (Rogoff, 2021; Baussola and Carvelli, 2023). Interestingly, while the latest decades have been characterised by a steady increase in global public debt (Kose et al., 2022; Rogoff, 2022; Carvelli, 2023), many countries – mainly advanced – have experienced growth rates of productivity much below the growth rates of aggregate output (Fernald et al., 2023) – despite the rapid spread of digital technologies (Ciaffi et al., 2022; Wang, 2023). Therefore, it appears crucial to further investigate whether and how discretionary fiscal policy affects the long-run dynamics of productivity.
While several related studies have been proposed in recent years, the results are often controversial. In addition, most of them focus on the effects of fiscal budget variations on aggregate output rather than productivity. As we can deduce from a stream of articles, any expansionary effect of fiscal policy on aggregate growth does not necessarily imply improvements in capital accumulation, productivity or vice-versa (e.g. Pereira, 2000; Blanchard and Perotti, 2002). The evidence of productivity enhancements associated with fiscal austerity (e.g. Dar and Amirkhalkhali, 2002; Schoonackers and Heylen, 2011; Everaert et al., 2015; Castro, 2017) contrasts with the findings of detrimental effects of government surpluses (Hernández De Cos and Moral-Benito, 2013; Yang et al., 2015; Bardaka et al., 2021). We cannot rule out that the divergence in the results is to a large extent due to the different econometric approaches and time horizons considered. Moreover, the productivity effects of discretionary fiscal policies might depend on the way governments run budget surplus/deficits – as it likely occurs for aggregate output (see Alesina and Perotti, 1997).
We depart from the existing literature by exploiting recent advances in the macro-panel literature that allow us to simultaneously address the following issues. Firstly, we isolate the causal effects going from fiscal consolidation to total factor productivity (TFP) by modelling reverse causality. Secondly, we build a dynamic heterogeneous empirical framework to account for heterogeneous cross-country effects and unobservable global factors. Thirdly, we allow for unit root processes of both the variables and the unobserved factors, as well as long-run effects and cointegration. Fourthly, our specifications encompass the fiscal feedback effects and the autoregressive behaviour of TFP. Fifthly, we employ the government structural balance as a measure of deficit/surplus in place of the more widely used cyclically adjusted primary balance (CAPB), in order to maximise our sample's dimension – a fundamental aspect for the inference techniques employed in this panel.
Although some of these issues have already been addressed in part of the above-mentioned studies, especially as it concerns the existence of unobserved global factors (e.g. Schoonackers and Heylen, 2011; Everaert et al., 2015), to the best of our knowledge this is the first empirical analysis that models reverse causality and feedback effects while addressing non-stationarity, country heterogeneity, global common shocks and cointegration. As we will see throughout the article, the robustness of the estimates and the performance of the models is assessed with additional empirical exercises related to both the economic and inferential spheres of the phenomenon under analysis.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 discusses the relevance of TFP for economic growth in the long-run; Section 3 describes the data and implements panel unit root and cointegration tests; Section 4 outlines the econometric strategy; Section 5 discusses the baseline results; Section 6 conducts a battery of robustness checks; Section 7 concludes the study.
2. TFP as a driver of long-run economic growth
The purpose of this section is to briefly discuss the existing links between TFP and economic growth, in order to underline the relevance of the phenomenon under analysis for the economies within a long-run perspective. Although, as mentioned before, the trajectories of TFP and aggregate growth do not necessarily move in the same direction, the long-run dynamics of economic growth are likely to depend to a huge extent on the evolution of TFP, thus motivating the relevance for the macroeconomy of additional analyses on TFP. The existing studies, both theoretical and empirical, highlight the importance of TFP for economic growth, especially when looking at the long-run effects. The main growth models which are constructed on an aggregate production function generally suggest that TFP does determine growth paths and cross-country differences in terms of steady-state level of output, regardless of whether TFP enters the model exogenously (Solow, 1957) or endogenously (e.g. Romer, 1990; Mankiw et al., 1992). Consistently, the seminal work of Caselli (2005) confirms that TFP explains the main cross-country differences in terms of output per capita – mainly because of the different capacities of countries to access the worldwide available technology. Other relevant empirical studies support the findings of strong ties between TFP and economic growth (e.g. Krugman, 1997; Hall and Jones, 1999; Baier et al., 2006), either when considering technical progress or variations in technical efficiency – the two basic components of TFP growth (Danquah et al., 2014). Recent empirical evidence suggests that TFP may affect growth both directly and indirectly, through its effects on inputs (Jia et al., 2020). Therefore, the studies on the TFP effects of discretionary fiscal policy could shed light on the transmission channels through which governments may stimulate economic growth and its components.
3. Data and statistical properties
We conduct the panel analysis by employing annual data for 73 countries over the period 1980–2019. Data on TFP and real output per capita are gathered from the PWT database (Feenstra et al., 2015). As it concerns our measure of fiscal adjustment, we use the government structural balance (as a % of potential GDP) of the IMF's World Economic Outlook (Edition of April 2023). Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics for the full sample and the two subsamples represented by the OECD and non-OECD groups. As we will discuss in the course of the article, the bipartition of the sample into OECD and non-OECD follows the existing empirical literature on the determinants of TFP (e.g. Färe et al., 1994; Danquah et al., 2014). It is worth highlighting that, according to the summary statistics, the fiscal deficit in the OECD area is greater compared to the non-OECD group, thus suggesting that the OECD countries' fiscal stances are more frequently characterised by expansionary policies.
Since the time dimension of the panel is large enough, we investigate the stationarity properties of the variable by employing the so-called CIPS panel unit root test developed by Pesaran (2007). Such a test appears to be the most appropriate to accommodate the economic and statistical features of the phenomenon, as it allows for heterogeneous autoregressive parameters and cross-sectional dependence. The outcomes of the CIPS test, reported in Table A2, suggest that the variables are non-stationary in levels and stationary in first differences.
As a further step, we verify whether our variables of interest are cointegrated by implementing the panel cointegration test proposed by Westerlund (2007). Such a testing procedure consists of four versions – which in turn are grouped into group-mean and panel tests, depending on the alternative hypothesis specified – and allows for heterogeneous effects and correlation of the error within and across the sections. Unlike most of the existing cointegration tests, the Westerlund test is not based on the distribution of the residuals, as it builds on auxiliary conditional ECM equations and investigates the behaviour of the speed of adjustment term. The results, shown in Table A3, are consistent across the four versions of the test and suggest that TFP and fiscal structural balance are cointegrated, irrespective of whether the levels of output enter the cointegrating vector.
4. Econometric strategy
4.1 Endogeneity and heterogeneity
Since the variables are non-stationary in levels, we begin our analysis by specifying a short-run dynamic equation. By denoting with
The main problem when modelling the nexus between fiscal budget and TFP is endogeneity since discretional fiscal policy can be to a relevant extent affected by current and lagged productivity fluctuations (Hernández De Cos and Moral-Benito, 2013). On the theoretical side, the existence of a reverse causal mechanism linking fiscal policy to TFP – and thus to government structural balance – is mostly due to the automatic stabilisers of government expenditure and the countercyclical nature of discretionary fiscal policy (e.g. Taylor, 2000; Andrés and Doménech, 2006; Fontana, 2009; Chen and Guo, 2013). For instance, a recent study proposed by Sanz-Córdoba (2020) provides both theoretical and empirical evidence suggesting that the less (more) productive countries might impose higher (lower) tax rates to achieve a given level of tax revenue. Therefore, the main challenge is the identification of
As we can see, Equation (2) follows the same structure as Equation (1), except for the lack of contemporaneous effects going from
4.2 Cointegration and unobserved global factors
In this section, we extend Equation (4) to accommodate the presence of unobserved global factors affecting TFP. The relevant role of unobserved heterogeneity in explaining cross-country TFP differentials arises in Danquah et al. (2014), as the latter can be seen as a global process with country-specific absorptive capacity (Parente and Prescott, 2002; De Visscher et al., 2017). Therefore, the presence of common factors within the sample related to productivity and the dynamics of technology introduces a problem of cross-sectional dependence (Schoonackers and Heylen, 2011). If the common effects were not properly modelled, the estimates of the coefficients would likely be biased (Everaert and De Groote, 2016). Thus, we model the following structure of the error term:
Since the two variables are
The baseline inferential technique employed to estimate Equation (6) is the pooled mean group estimator (PMG) proposed by Pesaran et al. (1999) as it allows short-run heterogeneous effects of both the covariates and the common shocks. The PMG estimator imposes cross-country homogeneity of the long-run coefficients and a common equilibrium path. To give a further sense of robustness, we also model heterogeneously the long-run nexus between fiscal adjustments and TFP by employing the MG estimator of Pesaran and Smith (1995). Although PMG normally gains efficiency relative to MG (Arnold et al., 2011), the latter provides consistent estimates as our
5. Baseline results
Table 2 shows the estimates of Equation (6). Unlike Model A, Model B controls for the levels of output per capita (whose associated long-run coefficient is
The impact of improvements in the fiscal budget is positive and significant – provided that GDP per capita is controlled for. The latter condition is crucial as it suggests that the long-run enhancements in productivity following episodes of fiscal consolidation emerge only if the fiscal surplus is run in such a way that long-run aggregate output growth is not negatively affected. In other words, such results emphasise the role of the structure of fiscal adjustments. For instance, if fiscal consolidation is accompanied by a shift of public resources from unproductive to productive expenditure, the marginal productivity of capital would be positively impacted, thus with beneficial effects on the long-run dynamics of TFP. Indeed, such a mechanism is consistent with theoretical and empirical findings which underline a high degree of complementarity between public and private capital (e.g. Aschauer, 1989; Abiad et al., 2016). On the contrary, if fiscal consolidation is run by increasing corporate taxes, it would end up with negative long-run effects on TFP as it obstacles the capacities of the economies to reduce their gap with the global technological frontier – consistently with the arguments proposed by Schoonackers and Heylen (2011) and Everaert et al. (2015). The effects of short-run variations in the fiscal budget are insignificant in pooled models, whereas some evidence of significant effects emerges in MG estimates. Although the short- and long-run estimated coefficients are slightly higher in the fully heterogeneous models, the results in terms of sign and significance are closely aligned. The speed of adjustment term, ranging from −0.8004 to −0.7155, is significant across all the specifications, suggesting that the economies' adjustment to the (common or country-specific) equilibrium path following a shock in productivity is fast.
It is worth pointing out that the similar long-run estimates between pooled and heterogeneous models do not necessarily imply that the underlying relationship is homogeneous across the countries, as the MG estimates rather reflect an average effect without ruling out the presence of a relevant share of observations that behaves much different from the mass of the distribution. Therefore, as a general rule, it appears convenient to estimate, in addition to pooled models, fully heterogeneous regressions since the TFP levels and dynamics are profoundly different across the economies – even when considering subsets of countries that share similar structural characteristics – although allowing for long-run heterogeneity represents a cost in terms of efficiency (Arnold et al., 2011).
6. Robustness checks
Although in the previous section we evaluate the robustness of the estimates of Equation (6) by considering several methodological alternatives, as well as by assessing the behaviour of the model when a key additional control – the output per capita – is controlled for, in this section we aim at further testing the robustness of the estimates by including additional sets of controls. In addition, we conduct additional empirical exercises in order to address different economic aspects of the phenomenon under analysis, given the availability of our data of interest. Therefore, we proceed as follows.
Firstly, we estimate the models for the full sample by adding as an additional control the international openness index – defined as the sum of imports and exports over GDP (Table A5). Such a choice is due to the relevance of international trade and competition for the dynamics of TFP, especially within a long-run perspective. Moreover, we report in Table A6 the estimates for the entire sample when the full set of controls is considered – i.e. when we control for the demographic trajectories and the financial environment, proxied by the population share of the labour force and the inflation rate, respectively. Such controls are carefully chosen following the existing empirical literature (e.g. Grossman and Helpman, 1993; Beaudry and Green, 2002; Acemoglu, 2010; Danquah et al., 2014) and accounting for the availability of data. The latter aspect is particularly relevant and represents the main constraint in our case since the empirical setup proposed in this study requires sufficiently large
Secondly, we make a bipartition of the sample into OECD and non-OECD countries (Table A6 and Table A7), in order to assess whether and to which extent the relationship differs across the two groups [2]. Although the estimates for the full sample suggest that the relationship under analysis is significantly heterogeneous across the countries, grouping the units into two main categories could provide useful economic insights (see, for instance, Färe et al. (1994)). Danquah et al. (2014) highlight that the determinants of TFP differ between OECD and non-OECD groups. Consistently, we chose the additional controls for the two groups according to the results proposed by Danquah et al. (2014).
Thirdly, since the period 1980–2019 was characterised by several social, political and economic shocks, we split the time interval by considering, separately, the 2007 global financial crisis (Table A8 and Table A9) and the 2011 European sovereign debt crisis (Table A10 and Table A11). Using 2007 and 2011 as time thresholds appears to be an acceptable compromise between the detail degree of the subperiods considered and the need to maintain a large enough time dimension to consistently estimate the coefficients – especially when assuming long-run slope heterogeneity. Moreover, the two events considered represent the most relevant economic disruptions over the time horizon employed in this study. Since the bipartition of the time dimension implies a substantial restriction of the time spans, we consider as the control variable only the output per capita in order to avoid further losses of observations and reductions in the cross-sectional dimension. Furthermore, considering that the time-splitting process drastically reduces the temporal dimension and the total number of observations, especially when considering the regressions post 2008 and 2011, we do not report the estimates for some of the specifications that require a positive number of lags of the cross-sectional averages in order to maintain a sufficient large dimension of
The overall results for the whole sample closely align with their baseline counterparts, except for a slighter magnitude long-run effect of budget surpluses, with no relevant differences when the long-run nexus between fiscal budget and TFP is modelled heterogeneously. No diverging conclusions arise even when splitting the time interval. As it concerns the distinction between OECD and non-OECD groups, we can notice some relevant differences. Unlike for the OECD countries, the significance of the estimates associated with the non-OECD economies appears to be slightly different compared to the full sample regressions. Indeed, while within the OECD area fiscal consolidation stimulates TFP in the long-run, if the fiscal adjustment is not contractionary for the aggregate output, such evidence is weaker for the non-OECD subsample. In fact, as all the controls are included in the model, the significant effect of government structural balance disappears for non-OECD economies. This might be to a relevant extent due to the higher marginal product to capital and expected growth rates when the economies' output levels are relatively far from their steady-state levels, thus compensating on average any detrimental long-run effect of deficit-financed unproductive expenditure on TFP. However, it is worth stressing that cross-country heterogeneity is significant even within the OECD and non-OECD groups, thus suggesting parsimony when proposing general policy recommendations.
7. Concluding remarks
The economic and financial global shocks that occurred over the past two decades have pushed governments, mainly in advanced economies, to stimulate growth and contrast social disruptions by massively resorting to deficit-financed expenditures, thus raising serious concerns about the sustainability of public finances in a long-term perspective. At the same time, the growth of productivity is weak or even negative in several countries, likely triggering the existing slowdowns in aggregate output growth. Since the empirical literature provides evidence of significant links between fiscal policy and productivity, it seems to be useful for both academics and policymakers to further investigate additional features of the phenomenon.
This article contributes to the literature on the nexus between fiscal policy and productivity by estimating the effects of fiscal adjustments on TFP while accounting for endogeneity, non-stationarity, country heterogeneity, fiscal feedback effects and global unobserved factors. The overall results suggest that improvements in fiscal structural balance stimulate the long-run dynamics of TFP if the government surplus does not exert downturns in aggregate output. Therefore, the productivity effects of fiscal consolidations are likely to depend on the way policymakers combine variations in expenditure and taxation – similar to what is suggested in Alesina and Perotti (1997) for the effects of fiscal adjustments on aggregate output. Consistently with the arguments provided in Schoonackers and Heylen (2011) and Banerjee and Zampolli (2019), it appears reasonable to state that any fiscal adjustment that improves the efficiency of public resource allocation ends up with beneficial effects for the TFP's long-run dynamics through improvements in the economies' access to the worldwide available technology. Conversely, running fiscal surpluses by cutting productive expenditure and/or by increasing the fiscal burden on firms through distortive taxation may offset the positive effects exerted by more sustainable fiscal stances, and could imply a reduction in public and private capital accumulation (Calderón et al., 2015; Bardaka et al., 2021; Baussola and Carvelli, 2023), with detrimental effects on the long-run dynamics of TFP. However, it is worth pointing out that while the findings for the full sample are broadly confirmed for the OECD subsample, neutral long-run effects of fiscal structural balance arise when the sample is restricted to the non-OECD countries – thus suggesting that the transmission channels linking fiscal policy to productivity could be different for the two groups. In fact, the differences in terms of TFP dynamics and determinants between OECD and non-OECD countries were already discussed by Färe et al., (1994) and Danquah et al. (2014) and are likely due, to a large extent, to the different social, political and economic environments – although we find evidence of cross-country heterogeneity even within the non-OECD group.
Considering the results that arose in the existing literature and this study, we believe that further research should investigate how the single components of government expenditure and revenues, as well as their combinations, affect the dynamics of TFP and how any significant effect evolves from the short-to the long-run. Moreover, employing the government budget constraint (GBC) in the model might provide useful insights and disentangle whether and how the effects on productivity exerted by fiscal expansion (austerity) depend on the goods and services financed (cut) and/or by the reduction (raise) in specific categories of tax and non-tax revenues.
Summary statistics
Variables | Obs | Mean | Std. Dev | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Full sample | |||||
TFP (log) | 1716 | −0.052 | 0.103 | −0.729 | 0.212 |
General gov. structural balance (% of potential GDP) | 1716 | −2.205 | 3.218 | −19.155 | 7.763 |
Output-side real GDP per capita (ppp) | 1716 | 28018.389 | 16737.134 | 1976.453 | 102622.45 |
OECD | |||||
TFP (log) | 673 | −0.038 | 0.082 | −0.324 | 0.212 |
General gov. structural balance (% of potential GDP) | 673 | −2.328 | 3.210 | −19.155 | 5.505 |
Output-side real GDP per capita (ppp) | 673 | 39687.363 | 13605.848 | 11893.271 | 102622.45 |
Non-OECD | |||||
TFP (log) | 1043 | −0.061 | 0.114 | −0.729 | 0.168 |
General gov. structural balance (% of potential GDP) | 1043 | −2.126 | 3.223 | −14.233 | 7.763 |
Output-side real GDP per capita (ppp) | 1043 | 20488.937 | 14035.063 | 1976.453 | 82761.758 |
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Baseline estimates
Model A | Model B | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
PMG | ||||||||||
0.2323*** | 0.2186*** | 0.2041*** | 0.2064*** | 0.2002*** | 0.2253*** | 0.2067*** | 0.2100*** | 0.2075*** | 0.2181*** | |
(0.0110) | (0.0129) | (0.0126) | (0.0140) | (0.0194) | (0.0102) | (0.0114) | (0.0136) | (0.0182) | (0.0276) | |
0.0007 | 0.0005 | 0.0005 | 0.0004 | 0.0005 | 0.0007 | 0.0004 | 0.0006 | 0.0004 | −0.0000 | |
(0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0008) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0009) | |
0.0015** | 0.0009 | 0.0008 | 0.0009 | 0.0012 | 0.0019*** | 0.0016*** | 0.0015** | 0.0016** | 0.0017* | |
(0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0016) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0010) | |
0.0020*** | 0.0015** | 0.0017** | 0.0018** | 0.0016* | ||||||
(0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0008) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | ||||||
−0.7765*** | −0.7747*** | −0.7828*** | −0.7598*** | −0.7634*** | −0.7838*** | −0.7822*** | −0.7685*** | −0.7482*** | −0.7155*** | |
(0.0174) | (0.0156) | (0.0201) | (0.0334) | (0.0450) | (0.0157) | (0.0184) | (0.0253) | (0.0437) | (0.0753) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,566 [73] | 1,556 [72] | 1,442 [68] | 1,303 [62] | 1,062 [48] | 1,510 [68] | 1,427 [62] | 1,158 [48] | 1,080 [46] | 885 [37] |
RMSE | 0.00629 | 0.00549 | 0.00539 | 0.00502 | 0.00505 | 0.00609 | 0.00506 | 0.00475 | 0.00458 | 0.00448 |
CSD p-value | 1.26e-09 | 0.502 | 0.431 | 0.911 | 0.472 | 0.00746 | 0.00531 | 4.13e-09 | 7.59e-06 | 0.980 |
MG | ||||||||||
0.2007*** | 0.2006*** | 0.2012*** | 0.2008*** | 0.2009*** | 0.2012*** | 0.2008*** | 0.2009*** | 0.2007*** | 0.1996*** | |
(0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | |
0.0010* | 0.0009* | 0.0012** | 0.0010** | 0.0011** | 0.0012** | 0.0010** | 0.0011** | 0.0010** | 0.0004 | |
(0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0004) | |
0.0004 | 0.0004 | 0.0004 | 0.0002 | 0.0000 | 0.0024*** | 0.0024*** | 0.0027*** | 0.0025*** | 0.0025*** | |
(0.0008) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0009) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | |
0.0027*** | 0.0025*** | 0.0025*** | 0.0024*** | 0.0017*** | ||||||
(0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | ||||||
−0.7993*** | −0.7994*** | −0.7988*** | −0.7992*** | −0.7991*** | −0.7988*** | −0.7992*** | −0.7991*** | −0.7993*** | −0.8004*** | |
(0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,566 [73] | 1,556 [72] | 1,442 [68] | 1,303 [62] | 1,062 [48] | 1,510 [68] | 1,427 [62] | 1,158 [48] | 1,080 [46] | 885 [37] |
RMSE | 6.66e-10 | 6.20e-10 | 5.79e-10 | 5.55e-10 | 5.10e-10 | 6.11e-10 | 5.75e-10 | 5.48e-10 | 4.96e-10 | 4.97e-10 |
CSD p-value | 0.00148 | 0.0322 | 0.00544 | 0.0488 | 0.157 | 0.724 | 0.571 | 0.460 | 0.925 | 0.709 |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence (CSD) test are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
List of countries
OECD | Non-OECD | |
---|---|---|
Australia | Angola | Lithuania |
Austria | Argentina | Malaysia |
Belgium | Brazil | Malta |
Canada | Bulgaria | Mauritius |
Denmark | Chile | Mexico |
Finland | China | Morocco |
France | China, Hong Kong SAR | Panama |
Germany | Colombia | Paraguay |
Greece | Costa Rica | Peru |
Iceland | Croatia | Philippines |
Ireland | Cyprus | Poland |
Italy | Czech Republic | Republic of Korea |
Japan | Dominican Republic | Romania |
Luxembourg | Ecuador | Russian Federation |
Netherlands | Egypt | Serbia |
New Zealand | Estonia | Singapore |
Norway | Guatemala | Slovakia |
Portugal | Hungary | Slovenia |
Spain | India | South Africa |
Sweden | Indonesia | Switzerland |
Turkey | Israel | Taiwan |
United Kingdom | Jordan | Thailand |
USA | Kazakhstan | Tunisia |
Kyrgyzstan | Ukraine | |
Latvia | Uruguay |
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
CIPS panel unit root test
Levels | First differences | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Lags | 1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Without trend | ||||||
TFP | −1.142 | −1.468 | −1.311 | −4.962*** | −4.962*** | −5.002*** |
Gov. struc. bal | −2.229* | −2.091 | −2.129 | −5.875*** | −5.875*** | −5.668*** |
With trend | ||||||
TFP | −1.645 | −2.060 | −2.060 | −5.415*** | −5.415*** | −5.500*** |
Gov. struc. bal | −2.484 | −2.301 | −2.895** | −6.066*** | −6.066*** | −5.822*** |
Note(s): The CIPS test verifies the null hypothesis of non-stationarity. The optimal lag length is selected according to the Akaike information criterion. The linear time-trend term is included in the equations
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Westerlund test for cointegration
Without trend | With trend | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Lags | 1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Without GDP | ||||||
Panel statistics | ||||||
−3.152* | −4.001*** | −4.994*** | −1.519 | −3.745** | −5.090*** | |
−6.000*** | −5.283*** | −7.031*** | −2.313 | −5.544*** | −4.965*** | |
Group-mean statistics | ||||||
−2.099 | −4.298*** | −6.902*** | −3.509** | −3.511** | −3.719** | |
−1.012 | −5.722*** | −5.722*** | −2.171** | −4.699*** | −5.700*** | |
With GDP | ||||||
Panel statistics | ||||||
−1.320 | −3.989*** | −4.573*** | −1.414 | −3.401** | −3.616** | |
−1.031 | −2.520* | −2.909* | −1.555 | −3.806*** | −4.010*** | |
Group-mean statistics | ||||||
−3.540** | −3.212** | −3.688** | −3.313** | −3.981*** | −5.019*** | |
−1.031 | −5.430*** | −5.492*** | −1.356 | −5.008*** | −5.493*** |
Note(s): The test verifies the null hypothesis of no cointegration. The test statistics
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates with GDP and international openness as additional controls, full sample
PMG | MG | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
0.2289*** | 0.2178*** | 0.2118*** | 0.1936*** | 0.1612*** | 0.2010*** | 0.2002*** | 0.1989*** | 0.2007*** | 0.2013*** | |
(0.0187) | (0.0181) | (0.0213) | (0.0215) | (0.0350) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | |
0.0008 | 0.0004 | −0.0002 | 0.0009 | 0.0010 | 0.0010* | 0.0008 | 0.0010* | 0.0008* | 0.0004 | |
(0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0012) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0004) | (0.0008) | |
0.0007*** | 0.0006*** | 0.0008*** | 0.0009*** | 0.0011*** | 0.0011** | 0.0008* | 0.0012*** | 0.0010* | 0.0013** | |
(0.0002) | (0.0002) | (0.0002) | (0.0001) | (0.0002) | (0.0005) | (0.0004) | (0.0002) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | |
0.0021*** | 0.0016** | 0.0011 | 0.0027*** | 0.0034*** | 0.0026*** | 0.0021*** | 0.0013* | 0.0024*** | 0.0027*** | |
(0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0015) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0008) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | |
0.0023 | 0.0005 | 0.0035 | 0.0160 | 0.0273 | 0.0031** | 0.0010 | 0.0061 | 0.0060 | 0.0009 | |
(0.0061) | (0.0071) | (0.0173) | (0.0110) | (0.0176) | (0.0015) | (0.0018) | (0.0049) | (0.0037) | (0.0026) | |
−0.7611*** | −0.7566*** | −0.7527*** | −0.7895*** | −0.8280*** | −0.7990*** | −0.7998*** | −0.8011*** | −0.7993*** | −0.7987*** | |
(0.0228) | (0.0283) | (0.0423) | (0.0201) | (0.0359) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,170 [47] | 1,060 [41] | 642 [22] | 486 [16] | 374 [12] | 1,170 [47] | 1,060 [41] | 642 [22] | 486 [16] | 374 [12] |
RMSE | 0.00541 | 0.00434 | 0.00461 | 0.00341 | 0.00297 | 5.51e-10 | 5.18e-10 | 4.84e-10 | 4.59e-10 | 5.10e-10 |
CSD p-value | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.364 | 0.350 | 0.238 | 0.430 | 0.710 | 0.0572 | 0.811 |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates with the full set of controls, full sample
PMG | MG | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
0.2106*** | 0.1978*** | 0.1683*** | 0.1610*** | 0.1683*** | 0.1987*** | 0.1987*** | 0.1998*** | 0.1971*** | 0.1996*** | |
(0.0214) | (0.0238) | (0.0089) | (0.0098) | (0.0127) | (0.0012) | (0.0012) | (0.0010) | (0.0022) | (0.0008) | |
−0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0002 | 0.0000 | 0.0002 | −0.0000 | −0.0000 | 0.0005 | 0.0002 | 0.0004 | |
(0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0004) | (0.0004) | |
0.0011 | 0.0011* | 0.0012** | 0.0011 | 0.0014** | 0.0012 | 0.0012 | 0.0019*** | 0.0013** | 0.0017*** | |
(0.0008) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | |
0.0011 | 0.0016** | 0.0026*** | 0.0031*** | 0.0028*** | 0.0015** | 0.0013** | 0.0017** | 0.0017** | 0.0019** | |
(0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0008) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | |
0.0066 | 0.0004 | 0.0103** | 0.0204* | 0.0042 | 0.0084 | 0.0179 | 0.0239 | 0.0172 | 0.0308** | |
(0.0061) | (0.0051) | (0.0043) | (0.0108) | (0.0051) | (0.0069) | (0.0143) | (0.0309) | (0.0473) | (0.0122) | |
0.0128 | 0.0175 | 0.0102 | 0.0128*** | 0.0191* | 0.0092 | 0.0243** | 0.0122** | 0.0092 | 0.0258*** | |
(0.0143) | (0.0116) | (0.0354) | (0.0043) | (0.0100) | (0.0320) | (0.0094) | (0.0051) | (0.0320) | (0.0091) | |
0.0087 | −0.0050 | −0.0119 | −0.0119 | −0.0157 | −0.0037 | −0.0074 | −0.0087 | −0.0071 | −0.0349 | |
(0.0239) | (0.0151) | (0.0231) | (0.0087) | (0.0185) | (0.0072) | (0.0101) | (0.0133) | (0.0143) | (0.0232) | |
−0.7807*** | −0.8073*** | −0.8436*** | −0.8509*** | −0.8474*** | −0.8013*** | −0.8013*** | −0.8002*** | −0.7912*** | −0.8004*** | |
(0.0319) | (0.0244) | (0.0284) | (0.0106) | (0.0293) | (0.0012) | (0.0012) | (0.0010) | (0.0097) | (0.0008) | |
Obs. [N] | 961 [39] | 961 [39] | 885 [36] | 821 [34] | 698 [28] | 961 [39] | 961 [39] | 885 [36] | 821 [34] | 698 [28] |
RMSE | 0.00438 | 0.00350 | 0.00315 | 0.00290 | 0.00268 | 5.85e-10 | 5.47e-10 | 4.72e-10 | 4.43e-10 | 4.20e-10 |
CSD p-value | 4.85e-06 | 0.271 | 0.683 | 0.480 | 0.282 | 0.00295 | 0.0278 | 0.00725 | 0.543 | 0.119 |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s):The author's own elaboration
Estimates, OECD vs non-OECD. PMG
CSA lags | No CSA | 3 | No CSA | 3 | No CSA | CSA | No CSA | 3 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
OECD | ||||||||
0.2079*** | 0.2083*** | 0.2118*** | 0.2000*** | 0.1852*** | 0.2241*** | 0.2013*** | 0.2013*** | |
(0.0046) | (0.0394) | (0.0068) | (0.0516) | (0.0107) | (0.0153) | (0.0089) | (0.0089) | |
0.0008 | 0.0007 | 0.0008 | 0.0003 | 0.0006 | 0.0007 | 0.0009 | 0.0009 | |
(0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | |
0.0024 | 0.0126 | 0.0027** | 0.0023** | 0.0022*** | 0.0171 | 0.0024*** | 0.0024*** | |
(0.0199) | (0.0114) | (0.0013) | (0.0010) | (0.0008) | (0.0173) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | |
0.0027** | 0.0014** | 0.0031** | 0.0027*** | |||||
(0.0012) | (0.0007) | (0.0013) | (0.0006) | |||||
0.0063 | 0.0101** | 0.0142** | 0.0170** | |||||
(0.0047) | (0.0041) | (0.0057) | (0.0075) | |||||
0.0028 | 0.0000 | 0.0074 | 0.0249 | |||||
(0.0097) | (0.0066) | (0.0101) | (0.0186) | |||||
0.0168** | 0.0088 | 0.0052 | 0.0080 | |||||
(0.0075) | (0.0065) | (0.0139) | (0.0186) | |||||
−0.7886*** | −0.8367*** | −0.7841*** | −0.8499*** | −0.7977*** | −0.8241*** | −0.7963*** | −0.8080*** | |
(0.0124) | (0.0225) | (0.0149) | (0.0376) | (0.0246) | (0.0440) | (0.0074) | (0.0061) | |
Obs. [N] | 464 [17] | 413 [17] | 464 [17] | 384[15] | 430 [17] | 415 [16] | 384 [15] | 276 [10] |
RMSE | 0.00341 | 0.00225 | 0.00340 | 0.00170 | 0.00341 | 0.00271 | 0.00233 | 0.00139 |
CSD p-value | 0.000 | 0.0778 | 0.000 | 0.792 | 1.85e-06 | 0.556 | 0.673 | 0.688 |
Non-OECD | ||||||||
0.2370*** | 0.2017*** | 0.2320*** | 0.1729*** | 0.2265*** | 0.2069*** | 0.2094*** | 0.2051*** | |
(0.0128) | (0.0222) | (0.0173) | (0.0416) | (0.0122) | (0.0160) | (0.0229) | (0.0246) | |
0.0007 | 0.0002 | 0.0004 | 0.0002 | 0.0007 | 0.0004 | 0.0003 | −0.0004 | |
(0.0006) | (0.0008) | (0.0006) | (0.0010) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0012) | |
0.0014 | 0.0011 | 0.0016** | 0.0013** | 0.0014** | 0.0014* | 0.0013 | 0.0008 | |
(0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0012) | (0.0012) | |
0.0015** | 0.0007 | 0.0017** | 0.0015* | |||||
(0.0006) | (0.0015) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | |||||
−0.4484** | 0.0236 | 0.2241 | 0.1532 | |||||
(0.2273) | (0.2265) | (0.2655) | (0.3225) | |||||
0.0001 | −0.0001 | −0.0002 | 0.0004 | |||||
(0.0002) | (0.0002) | (0.0004) | (0.0003) | |||||
−0.7756*** | −0.7479*** | −0.7777*** | −0.7663*** | −0.7852*** | −0.7742*** | −0.7606*** | −0.7076*** | |
(0.0187) | (0.0437) | (0.0267) | (0.0872) | (0.0174) | (0.0245) | (0.0327) | (0.0859) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,248 [56] | 1,029 [51] | 1,248 [56] | 707 [30] | 1,080 [51] | 384 [14] | 1,079 [51] | 376 [14] |
RMSE | 0.00749 | 0.00591 | 0.00735 | 0.00509 | 0.00685 | 0.00580 | 0.00514 | 0.00549 |
CSD p-value | 0.00111 | 0.561 | 0.061 | 0.624 | 0.0499 | 0.960 | 0.599 | 0.492 |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates, OECD vs non-OECD. MG
CSA lags | No CSA | 3 | No CSA | 3 | No CSA | CSA | No CSA | 3 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
OECD | ||||||||
0.1996*** | 0.2000*** | 0.1996*** | 0.2000*** | 0.1996*** | 0.1999*** | 0.2000*** | 0.1988*** | |
(0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | |
0.0005 | 0.0006 | 0.0005 | 0.0006 | 0.0005 | 0.0006 | 0.0006 | 0.0009*** | |
(0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0000) | |
−0.0142 | −0.0058 | 0.0017** | 0.0019** | 0.0010 | 0.0011 | 0.0028** | 0.0023** | |
(0.0286) | (0.0207) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0013) | (0.0010) | |
0.0017** | 0.0019** | 0.0017** | 0.0019** | |||||
(0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | |||||
0.0099*** | 0.0096* | 0.0104 | 0.0080 | |||||
(0.0028) | (0.0057) | (0.0080) | (0.0151) | |||||
0.0262 | 0.0126 | 0.0283 | 0.0194 | |||||
(0.0393) | (0.0274) | (0.0308) | (0.0466) | |||||
0.0001*** | −0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0002 | |||||
(0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0001) | (0.0002) | |||||
−0.8004*** | −0.8004*** | −0.8004*** | −0.8000*** | −0.8004*** | −0.8001*** | −0.8000*** | −0.8012*** | |
(0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0011) | |
Obs. [N] | 464 [17] | 430 [17] | 464 [17] | 384 [15] | 430 [17] | 415 [16] | 384 [15] | 276 [10] |
RMSE | 5.45e-10 | 5.20e-10 | 4.88e-10 | 3.46e-10 | 4.61e-10 | 4.24e-10 | 3.63e-10 | 3.57e-10 |
CSD p-value | 0.910 | 0.106 | 0.00374 | 0.934 | 0.545 | 0.623 | 0.755 | 0.0826 |
Non-OECD | ||||||||
0.2298*** | 0.1943*** | 0.2267*** | 0.2092*** | 0.2017*** | 0.2011*** | 0.2013*** | 0.1990*** | |
(0.0166) | (0.0320) | (0.0159) | (0.0164) | (0.0014) | (0.0013) | (0.0013) | (0.0018) | |
0.0005 | 0.0003 | 0.0011 | 0.0013** | 0.0015** | 0.0012* | 0.0013** | 0.0001 | |
(0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0009) | |
0.0014 | 0.0011 | 0.0016** | 0.0013** | 0.0010*** | 0.0011*** | 0.0013 | 0.0009 | |
(0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0001) | (0.0002) | (0.0011) | (0.0008) | |
0.0026*** | 0.0028*** | 0.0028*** | 0.0022** | |||||
(0.0009) | (0.0008) | (0.0008) | (0.0009) | |||||
−0.6722 | 1.1463 | 1.4176 | 4.3855 | |||||
(0.4639) | (1.2385) | (1.2189) | (3.1496) | |||||
0.0000 | −0.0001* | −0.0001 | 0.0002 | |||||
(0.0000) | (0.0001) | (0.0001) | (0.0002) | |||||
−0.7828*** | −0.7542*** | −0.7990*** | −0.7987*** | −0.7983*** | −0.7989*** | −0.7987*** | −0.8010*** | |
(0.0262) | (0.0579) | (0.0014) | (0.0012) | (0.0014) | (0.0013) | (0.0013) | (0.0018) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,248 [56] | 1,029 [51] | 1,136 [56] | 708 [33] | 1,080 [51] | 331 [12] | 1,077 [51] | 329 [12] |
RMSE | 0.00749 | 0.00591 | 7.19e-10 | 6.23e-10 | 6.72e-10 | 6.45e-10 | 5.74e-10 | 5.56e-10 |
CSD p-value | 0.00111 | 0.561 | 0.0296 | 0.363 | 0.551 | 0.547 | 0.0244 | 0.667 |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates, pre and post 2007, PMG
Model A | Model B | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
<2008 | ||||||||||
0.2244*** | 0.2228*** | 0.1897*** | 0.1729*** | 0.1595*** | 0.1911*** | 0.1896*** | 0.1540*** | 0.0953 | – | |
(0.0370) | (0.0441) | (0.0170) | (0.0232) | (0.0338) | (0.0173) | (0.0197) | (0.0388) | (0.0757) | – | |
0.0002 | −0.0001 | 0.0008 | 0.0011 | 0.0010 | 0.0012*** | 0.0011*** | 0.0014*** | 0.0010*** | – | |
(0.0008) | (0.0013) | (0.0008) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0002) | (0.0001) | (0.0002) | (0.0002) | – | |
0.0005 | 0.0011 | 0.0018 | 0.0014 | 0.0014 | 0.0014 | 0.0013 | 0.0026*** | 0.0031** | – | |
(0.0008) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0019) | (0.0008) | (0.0012) | – | |
0.0023** | 0.0029*** | 0.0041*** | 0.0031*** | – | ||||||
(0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | – | ||||||
−0.7409*** | −0.7159*** | −0.7858*** | −0.8080*** | −0.7953*** | −0.7866*** | −0.7904*** | −0.8143*** | −0.8427*** | – | |
(0.0633) | (0.0983) | (0.0209) | (0.0195) | (0.0437) | (0.0234) | (0.0106) | (0.0319) | (0.0218) | – | |
Obs. [N] | 726 [48] | 712 [46] | 589 [37] | 424 [23] | 381 [21] | 712 [46] | 468 [24] | 398 [20] | 298 [14] | – |
RMSE | 0.00462 | 0.00464 | 0.00348 | 0.00344 | 0.00320 | 0.00381 | 0.00322 | 0.00302 | 0.00197 | – |
CSD p-value | 5.84e-05 | 0.421 | 0.168 | 0.191 | 0.301 | 0.126 | 0.726 | 0.737 | 0.274 | – |
≥2008 | ||||||||||
0.2367*** | 0.2366*** | 0.2080*** | – | – | 0.2392*** | 0.2220*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0140) | (0.0164) | (0.0169) | – | – | (0.0144) | (0.0189) | – | – | – | |
0.0008 | 0.0007 | 0.0008 | – | – | 0.0007 | 0.0007 | – | – | – | |
(0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0007) | – | – | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | – | – | – | |
0.0009* | 0.0007 | 0.0006 | – | – | 0.0024*** | 0.0020*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | – | – | (0.0007) | (0.0005) | – | – | – | |
– | – | – | 0.0017*** | 0.0017*** | – | – | – | |||
– | – | – | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | – | – | – | |||
−0.7972*** | −0.7872*** | −0.8038*** | – | – | −0.7914*** | −0.7936*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0222) | (0.0167) | (0.0295) | – | – | (0.0218) | (0.0233) | – | – | – | |
Obs. [N] | 876 [73] | 876 [73] | 803 [73] | – | – | 876 [73] | 864 [72] | – | – | – |
RMSE | 0.00698 | 0.00582 | 0.00530 | – | – | 0.00684 | 0.00564 | – | – | – |
CSD p-value | 0.000718 | 0.0893 | 0.781 | – | – | 0.0318 | 0.118 | – | – | – |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates, pre and post 2007, MG
Model A | Model B | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
<2008 | ||||||||||
0.1996*** | 0.1988*** | 0.1996*** | 0.2000*** | 0.2008*** | 0.1996*** | 0.2003*** | 0.2018*** | 0.2008*** | – | |
(0.0009) | (0.0012) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0013) | – | |
0.0004 | 0.0000 | 0.0004 | 0.0006 | 0.0011* | 0.0004 | 0.0008 | 0.0015** | 0.0011 | – | |
(0.0004) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | – | |
0.0025*** | 0.0024*** | 0.0017*** | 0.0017*** | 0.0008 | 0.0017*** | 0.0012 | 0.0017*** | 0.0019*** | – | |
(0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0009) | (0.0005) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | – | |
0.0017*** | 0.0021*** | 0.0031*** | 0.0025** | – | ||||||
(0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0008) | – | ||||||
0.0017*** | −0.8012*** | −0.8004*** | −0.8000*** | −0.7992*** | −0.8004*** | −0.7997*** | −0.7982*** | −0.7992*** | – | |
(0.0009) | (0.0012) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0010) | (0.0011) | (0.0012) | (0.0013) | – | |
Obs. [N] | 726 [48] | 712 [46] | 589 [37] | 424 [23] | 381 [21] | 712 [46] | 468 [24] | 398 [20] | 298 [14] | – |
RMSE | 5.41e-10 | 5.17e-10 | 5.03e-10 | 5.04e-10 | 5.10e-10 | 4.95e-10 | 4.95e-10 | 4.63e-10 | 7.61e-10 | – |
CSD p-value | 0.0033 | 0.0038 | 0.0012 | 0.1482 | 0.2390 | 0.0131 | 0.136 | 0.168 | 0.758 | – |
≥2008 | ||||||||||
0.2007*** | 0.2006*** | 0.2007*** | – | – | 0.2007*** | 0.2007*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | – | – | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | – | – | – | |
0.0010* | 0.0009* | 0.0010* | – | – | 0.0010* | 0.0010* | – | – | – | |
(0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | – | – | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | – | – | – | |
0.0011** | 0.0010** | 0.0004 | – | – | 0.0027*** | 0.0029*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0004) | – | – | (0.0008) | (0.0010) | – | – | – | |
– | – | 0.0024*** | 0.0025*** | – | – | – | ||||
– | – | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | – | – | – | ||||
−0.7993*** | −0.7994*** | −0.7993*** | – | – | −0.7993*** | −0.7993*** | – | – | – | |
(0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | – | – | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | – | – | – | |
Obs. [N] | 876 [73] | 876 [73] | 803 [73] | – | – | 872 [73] | 862 [72] | – | – | – |
RMSE | 7.63e-10 | 6.49e-10 | 5.86e-10 | – | – | 7.27e-10 | 6.57e-10 | – | – | – |
CSD p-value | 0.0624 | 0.120 | 0.731 | – | – | 0.480 | 0.995 | – | – | – |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates, pre and post 2011. PMG
Model A | Model B | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
<2011 | ||||||||||
0.2101*** | 0.2084*** | 0.2098*** | 0.2214*** | 0.2190*** | 0.2217*** | 0.1942*** | 0.2052*** | 0.1932*** | 0.1897*** | |
(0.0122) | (0.0140) | (0.0214) | (0.0464) | (0.0686) | (0.0155) | (0.0199) | (0.0146) | (0.0212) | (0.0230) | |
0.0006 | 0.0003 | 0.0004 | −0.0000 | −0.0005 | 0.0005 | 0.0005 | −0.0002 | 0.0004 | 0.0006 | |
(0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0008) | (0.0011) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0010) | (0.0008) | (0.0009) | |
0.0019*** | 0.0013* | 0.0014 | 0.0008 | −0.0002 | 0.0019** | 0.0015 | 0.0025*** | 0.0027*** | 0.0022*** | |
(0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0009) | (0.0010) | (0.0015) | (0.0008) | (0.0011) | (0.0007) | (0.0010) | (0.0008) | |
0.0011 | 0.0027*** | 0.0021** | 0.0024* | 0.0017* | ||||||
(0.0012) | (0.0009) | (0.0009) | (0.0012) | (0.0009) | ||||||
−0.7673*** | −0.7503*** | −0.7269*** | −0.7232*** | −0.7186*** | −0.7499*** | −0.7668*** | −0.7463*** | −0.7898*** | −0.7904*** | |
(0.0182) | (0.0252) | (0.0489) | (0.0793) | (0.1351) | (0.0268) | (0.0293) | (0.0487) | (0.0193) | (0.0448) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,028 [67] | 969 [59] | 804 [46] | 718 [42] | 494 [25] | 969 [59] | 821 [45] | 516 [24] | 438 [20] | 326 [14] |
RMSE | 0.00627 | 0.00549 | 0.00495 | 0.00497 | 0.00523 | 0.00604 | 0.00506 | 0.00460 | 0.00355 | 0.00340 |
CSD p-value | 0.000 | 0.0234 | 0.00277 | 0.0500 | 0.417 | 2.17e-06 | 0.116 | 0.000458 | 0.865 | 0.159 |
≥2011 | ||||||||||
0.2265*** | – | – | – | – | 0.2007*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0170) | – | – | – | – | (0.0011) | – | – | – | – | |
0.0008 | – | – | – | – | 0.0010* | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0005) | – | – | – | – | (0.0005) | – | – | – | – | |
0.0012* | – | – | – | – | 0.0021*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0006) | – | – | – | – | (0.0005) | – | – | – | – | |
– | – | – | – | 0.0016*** | – | – | – | – | ||
– | – | – | – | (0.0006) | – | – | – | – | ||
−0.8044*** | – | – | – | – | −0.7993*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0271) | – | – | – | – | (0.0011) | – | – | – | – | |
Obs. [N] | 657 [73] | – | – | – | – | 648 [73] | – | – | – | – |
RMSE | 0.00551 | – | – | – | – | 5.06e-10 | – | – | – | – |
CSD p-value | 1.33e-10 | – | – | – | – | 0.488 | – | – | – | – |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Estimates, pre and post 2011. MG
Model A | Model B | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CSA lags | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | No CSA | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
<2011 | ||||||||||
0.2016*** | 0.2007*** | 0.2007*** | 0.2201*** | 0.1933*** | 0.2007*** | 0.2008*** | 0.1989*** | 0.1998*** | 0.2003*** | |
(0.0010) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0150) | (0.0037) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | |
0.0010** | 0.0007* | 0.0000 | 0.0004 | 0.0008 | 0.0010** | 0.0011** | 0.0001 | 0.0005 | 0.0008 | |
(0.0005) | (0.0004) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0006) | |
0.0030*** | 0.0024*** | 0.0024*** | 0.0018*** | 0.0011 | 0.0024*** | 0.0020*** | 0.0012* | 0.0017*** | 0.0022*** | |
(0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0005) | (0.0007) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | |
0.0024*** | 0.0025*** | 0.0013* | 0.0018*** | 0.0021*** | ||||||
(0.0006) | (0.0006) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | (0.0007) | ||||||
−0.7984*** | −0.7993*** | −0.7993*** | −0.6613*** | −0.8034*** | −0.7993*** | −0.7992*** | −0.8011*** | −0.8002*** | −0.7997*** | |
(0.0010) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.1326) | (0.0057) | (0.0010) | (0.0009) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | (0.0011) | |
Obs. [N] | 1,028 [67] | 969 [59] | 804 [46] | 718 [42] | 494 [25] | 969 [59] | 821 [45] | 516 [24] | 438 [20] | 326 [14] |
RMSE | 7.08e-10 | 6.65e-10 | 6.05e-10 | 5.87e-10 | 5.78e-10 | 6.89e-10 | 6.29e-10 | 5.84e-10 | 5.12e-10 | 5.25e-10 |
CSD p-value | 0.112 | 0.444 | 0.120 | 0.105 | 0.598 | 0.000607 | 0.0121 | 0.459 | 0.501 | 0.683 |
≥2011 | ||||||||||
0.2007*** | – | – | – | – | 0.1677*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0011) | – | – | – | – | (0.0327) | – | – | – | – | |
0.0010* | – | – | – | – | 0.0003 | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0005) | – | – | – | – | (0.0012) | – | – | – | – | |
0.0017* | – | – | – | – | 0.0024*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0009) | – | – | – | – | (0.0007) | – | – | – | – | |
– | – | – | – | 0.0024*** | – | – | – | – | ||
– | – | – | – | (0.0007) | – | – | – | – | ||
−0.7993*** | – | – | – | – | −0.8382*** | – | – | – | – | |
(0.0011) | – | – | – | – | (0.0317) | – | – | – | – | |
Obs. [N] | 657 [73] | – | – | – | – | 648 [73] | – | – | – | – |
RMSE | 7.95e-10 | – | – | – | – | 0.00252 | – | – | – | – |
CSD p-value | 0.938 | – | – | – | – | 0.661 | – | – | – | – |
Note(s): The asterisks ***, **, * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Linear country-specific trends are included in the models. The square brackets report the standard errors. The p-values of the cross-sectional dependence test (CSD) are reported. RMSE is the root mean squared error. CSA refers to the cross-sectional averages.
Source(s): The author's own elaboration
Notes
See Ramey (2011) and Abiad et al. (2016) for the relevance of lagged fiscal effects.
In this study, we categorise as OECD member the countries that entered the group by 1980 – that is the first year of the time span considered in the analysis. Such a choice is due to the willingness to avoid massive observation losses in the MG estimates, which would result by allowing the units to switch from one group to another over the period considered.
References
Abiad, A., Furceri, D. and Topalova, T. (2016), “The macroeconomic effects of public investment: evidence from advanced economies”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 50, pp. 224-240, doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2016.07.005.
Acemoglu, D. (2010), “When does labor scarcity encourage innovation?”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 118 No. 6, pp. 1037-1078, doi: 10.1086/658160.
Afonso, A. and Aubyn, St.M. (2010), “Public and private investment rates of return: evidence for industrialized countries”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 17 No. 9, pp. 839-843, doi: 10.1080/13504850802599425.
Aizenman, J., Kletzer, K. and Pinto, B. (2007), “Economic growth with constraints on tax revenues and public debt: implications for fiscal policy and cross-country differences”, doi: 10.3386/w12750.
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1997), “Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: composition and macroeconomic effects”, Staff Papers, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 210-248, doi: 10.2307/3867543.
Andrés, J. and Doménech, R. (2006), “Automatic stabilizers, fiscal rules and macroeconomic stability”, European Economic Review, Vol. 50 No. 6, pp. 1487-1506, doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.03.005.
Arnold, J., Bassanini, A. and Scarpetta, S. (2011), “Solow or Lucas? Testing speed of convergence on a panel of OECD countries”, Research in Economics, Vol. 65 No. 2, pp. 110-123, doi: 10.1016/j.rie.2010.11.005.
Aschauer, D.A. (1989), “Is public expenditure productive?”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 177-200, doi: 10.1016/0304-3932(89)90047-0.
Aschauer, D.A. (2000), “Do states optimize? Public capital and economic growth”, The Annals of Regional Science, Vol. 34, pp. 343-363, doi: 10.1007/s001689900016.
Baier, S.L., Dwyer, G.P. Jr and Tamura, R. (2006), “How important are capital and total factor productivity for economic growth?”, Economic Inquiry, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 23-49, doi: 10.1093/ei/cbj003.
Banerjee, R. and Zampolli, F. (2019), “What drives the short-run costs of fiscal consolidation? Evidence from OECD countries”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 82, pp. 420-436, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.01.023.
Bardaka, I., Bournakis, I. and Kaplanoglou, G. (2021), “Total factor productivity (TFP) and fiscal consolidation: how harmful is austerity?”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 94, pp. 908-922, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2020.02.032.
Barro, R.J. (1990), “Government spending in a simple model of endogeneous growth”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 No. 5, Part 2, pp. S103-S125, doi: 10.1086/261726.
Baussola, M. and Carvelli, G. (2023), “Public and private investments: long-run asymmetric effects in France and the US”, Finance Research Letters, Vol. 58, Part A, 104317, doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2023.104317.
Beaudry, P. and Green, D.A. (2002), “Population growth, technological adoption, and economic outcomes in the information era”, Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 749-774, doi: 10.1006/redy.2002.0189.
Blanchard, O. and Perotti, R. (2002), “An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 No. 4, pp. 1329-1368, doi: 10.1162/003355302320935043.
Calderón, C., Moral‐Benito, E. and Servén, L. (2015), “Is infrastructure capital productive? A dynamic heterogeneous approach”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 30 No. 2, pp. 177-198, doi: 10.1002/jae.2373.
Carvelli, G. (2023), “Exogenous variations in public debt and the private output: addressing country heterogeneity and cross-sectional dependence in a large panel”, Applied Economics, pp. 1-22, doi: 10.1080/00036846.2023.2177602.
Caselli, F. (2005), “Accounting for cross-country income differences”, Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, pp. 679-741, doi: 10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01009-9.
Castro, V. (2017), “The impact of fiscal consolidations on the functional components of government expenditures”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 60, pp. 138-150, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.09.027.
Chen, S.H. and Guo, J.T. (2013), “Progressive taxation and macroeconomic (In) stability with productive government spending”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 37 No. 5, pp. 951-963, doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2013.01.004.
Chudik, A. and Pesaran, M.H. (2015), “Common correlated effects estimation of heterogeneous dynamic panel data models with weakly exogenous regressors”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 188 No. 2, pp. 393-420, doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2015.03.007.
Ciaffi, G., Deleidi, M. and Di Bucchianico, S. (2022), Stagnation despite ongoing innovation: Is R&D expenditure composition a missing link? An empirical analysis for the US (1948-2019), Department of Economics, No. 877, University of Siena.
Cochrane, J.H. (2011), “Understanding policy in the great recession: some unpleasant fiscal arithmetic”, European Economic Review, Vol. 55 No. 1, pp. 2-30, doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.11.002.
Codogno, L., Favero, C. and Missale, A. (2003), “Yield spreads on EMU government bonds”, Economic Policy, Vol. 18 No. 37, pp. 503-532, doi: 10.1111/1468-0327.00114_1.
Danquah, M., Moral-Benito, E. and Ouattara, B. (2014), “TFP growth and its determinants: a model averaging approach”, Empirical Economics, Vol. 47, pp. 227-251, doi: 10.1007/s00181-013-0737-y.
Dar, A.A. and AmirKhalkhali, S. (2002), “Government size, factor accumulation, and economic growth: evidence from OECD countries”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 24 Nos 7-8, pp. 679-692, doi: 10.1016/S0161-8938(02)00163-1.
De Visscher, S., Eberhardt, M. and Everaert, G. (2017), “Measuring productivity and absorptive capacity evolution in OECD economies”, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP12261.
Elmendorf, D.W. and Mankiw, N.G. (1999), “Government debt”, Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, pp. 1615-1669, doi: 10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10038-7.
Everaert, G. and De Groote, T. (2016), “Common correlated effects estimation of dynamic panels with cross-sectional dependence”, Econometric Reviews, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 428-463, doi: 10.1080/07474938.2014.966635.
Everaert, G., Heylen, F. and Schoonackers, R. (2015), “Fiscal policy and TFP in the OECD: measuring direct and indirect effects”, Empirical Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 605-640, doi: 10.1007/s00181-014-0872-0.
Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Norris, M. and Zhang, Z. (1994), “Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries”, American Economic Review, Vol. 84, pp. 66-83.
Feenstra, R.C., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M.P. (2015), “The next generation of the penn World table”, American Economic Review, Vol. 105 No. 10, pp. 3150-3182, doi: 10.34894/QT5BCC.
Fernald, J., Inklaar, R. and Ruzic, D. (2023), “The productivity slowdown in advanced economies: common shocks or common trends?”, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series, pp. 2023-2107.
Fontana, G. (2009), “Whither new consensus macroeconomics? The role of government and fiscal policy in modern macroeconomics”, Levy Economics Institute, Working Paper 563.
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1993), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Hall, R.E. and Jones, C.I. (1999), “Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114 No. 1, pp. 83-116, doi: 10.1162/003355399555954.
Hernández De Cos, P. and Moral‐Benito, E. (2013), “Fiscal consolidations and economic growth”, Fiscal Studies, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 491-515, doi: 10.1111/j.1475-5890.2013.12017.x.
Jia, F., Ma, X., Xu, X. and Xie, L. (2020), “The differential role of manufacturing and non-manufacturing TFP growth in economic growth”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 52, pp. 174-183, doi: 10.1016/j.strueco.2019.10.006.
Juodis, A., Karabiyik, H. and Westerlund, J. (2021), “On the robustness of the pooled CCE estimator”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 220 No. 2, pp. 325-348, doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2020.06.002.
Kose, M.A., Ohnsorge, F.L., Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2022), “The aftermath of debt surges”, Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 14, pp. 637-663, doi: 10.1146/annurev-economics-051420-015343.
Krugman, P.R. (1997), The Age of Diminished Expectations: US Economic Policy in the 1990s, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Laubach, T. (2009), “New evidence on the interest rate effects of budget deficits and debt”, Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 858-885, doi: 10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.4.858.
Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. and Weil, D.N. (1992), “A contribution to the empirics of economic growth”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107 No. 2, pp. 407-437, doi: 10.2307/2118477.
Owusu, B., Bökemeier, B. and Greiner, A. (2023), “Assessing nonlinearities and heterogeneity in debt sustainability analysis: a panel spline approach”, Empirical Economics, Vol. 64 No. 3, pp. 1315-1346, doi: 10.1007/s00181-022-02284-8.
Parente, S.L. and Prescott, E.C. (2002), Barriers to Riches, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Pereira, A.M. (2000), “Is all public capital created equal?”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 82 No. 3, pp. 513-518, doi: 10.1162/rest.2000.82.3.513.
Pesaran, M.H. (2006), “Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure”, Econometrica, Vol. 74 No. 4, pp. 967-1012, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00692.x.
Pesaran, M.H. (2007), “A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross‐section dependence”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 22 No. 2, pp. 265-312, doi: 10.1002/jae.951.
Pesaran, M.H. and Smith, R. (1995), “Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68 No. 1, pp. 79-113, doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01644-F.
Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R.P. (1999), “Pooled mean group estimation of dynamic heterogeneous panels”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 94 No. 446, pp. 621-634, doi: 10.2307/2670182.
Ramey, V.A. (2011), “Identifying government spending shocks: it's all in the timing”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 126 No. 1, pp. 1-50, doi: 10.1093/qje/qjq008.
Rogoff, K. (2021), “Fiscal sustainability in the aftermath of the great pause”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 43 No. 4, pp. 783-793, doi: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2021.02.007.
Rogoff, K. (2022), “Emerging market sovereign debt in the aftermath of the pandemic”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 36 No. 4, pp. 147-166, doi: 10.1257/jep.36.4.147.
Romer, P.M. (1990), “Endogenous technological change”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 No. 5, Part 2, pp. S71-S102, doi: 10.1086/261725.
Sanz-Córdoba, P. (2020), “The role of infrastructure investment and factor productivity in international tax competition”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 85, pp. 30-38, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.05.003.
Schoonackers, R. and Heylen, F. (2011), Fiscal Policy and TFP in the OECD: A Non-stationary Panel Approach, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, No. 11/701, Ghent University.
Solow, R.M. (1957), “Technical change and the aggregate production function”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39 No. 3, pp. 312-320, doi: 10.2307/1926047.
Stauskas, O. (2023), “Complete theory for CCE under heterogeneous slopes and general unknown factors”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85 No. 2, pp. 283-303, doi: 10.1111/obes.12523.
Taylor, J.B. (2000), “Reassessing discretionary fiscal policy”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 21-36, doi: 10.1257/jep.14.3.21.
Wang, L. (2023), “Digital transformation and total factor productivity”, Finance Research Letters, 104338, doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2023.104338.
Westerlund, J. (2007), “Testing for error correction in panel data”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 69 No. 6, pp. 709-748, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0084.2007.00477.x.
Yang, W., Fidrmuc, J. and Ghosh, S. (2015), “Macroeconomic effects of fiscal adjustment: a tale of two approaches”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 57, pp. 31-60, doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2015.05.003.