Prelims

Value, Money, Profit, and Capital Today

ISBN: 978-1-80455-751-8, eISBN: 978-1-80455-750-1

ISSN: 0161-7230

Publication date: 20 November 2023

Citation

(2023), "Prelims", Herrera, R. (Ed.) Value, Money, Profit, and Capital Today (Research in Political Economy, Vol. 39), Emerald Publishing Limited, Leeds, pp. i-xix. https://doi.org/10.1108/S0161-723020230000039015

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024 Rémy Herrera. Published under exclusive licence by Emerald Publishing Limited


Half Title Page

Value, Money, Profit, and Capital Today

Series Title Page

Research in Political Economy

Series Editor: Paul Zarembka

State University of New York at Buffalo, USA

Recent Volumes:

Volume 21: Neoliberalism in Crisis, Accumulation, and Rosa Luxemburg's Legacy – Edited by P. Zarembka and S. Soederberg
Volume 22: The Capitalist State and Its Economy: Democracy in Socialism – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 23: The Hidden History of 9-11-2001 – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 24: Transitions in Latin America and in Poland and Syria – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 25: Why Capitalism Survives Crises: The Shock Absorbers – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 26: The National Question and the Question of Crisis – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 27: Revitalizing Marxist Theory for Today's Capitalism – Edited by P. Zarembka and R. Desai
Volume 28: Contradictions: Finance, Greed, and Labor Unequally Paid – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 29: Sraffa and Althusser Reconsidered; Neoliberalism Advancing in South Africa, England, and Greece – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 30A: Theoretical Engagements In Geopolitical Economy – Edited by R. Desai
Volume 30B: Analytical Gains of Geopolitical Economy – Edited by R. Desai
Volume 31: Risking Capitalism – Edited by S. Soederberg
Volume 32: Return of Marxian Macro-Dynamics in East Asia – Edited by M. Ishikura, S. Jeong, and M. Li
Volume 33: Environmental Impacts of Transnational Corporations in the Global South – Edited by P. Cooney and W. S. Freslon
Volume 34: Class History and Class Practices in the Periphery of Capitalism – Edited by P. Zarembka
Volume 35: The Capitalist Commodification of Animals – Edited by B. Clark and T. D. Wilson
Volume 36: Imperialism and Transitions to Socialism – Edited by R. Herrera
Volume 37: Polish Marxism after Luxemburg – Edited by J. Toporowski
Volume 38: Imperialism and the Political Economy of Global South's Debt – Edited by Ndongo Samba Sylla

Editorial Advisory Board

General Editor

  • Paul Zarembka

  • State University of New York at Buffalo, USA

Editorial Board

  • Radhika Desai

  • University of Manitoba, Canada

  • Thomas Ferguson

  • University of Massachusetts at Boston, USA

  • Seongjin Jeong

  • Gyeongsang National University, South Korea

  • Jie Meng

  • Fudan University, People's Republic of China

  • Isabel Monal

  • University of Havana, Cuba

  • Virginia Fontes

  • Fluminense Federal University, Brazil

  • Paul Cooney Seisdedos

  • Pontificia Universidad Catolica del ´Ecuador (PUCE), Ecuador

  • Jan Toporowski

  • The School of Oriental and African Studies, UK

Title Page

Research in Political Economy Volume 39

Value, Money, Profit, and Capital Today

Edited by

Rémy Herrera

National Center of the Scientific Research (CNRS), France

United Kingdom – North America – Japan – India – Malaysia – China

Copyright Page

Emerald Publishing Limited

Emerald Publishing, Floor 5, Northspring, 21-23 Wellington Street, Leeds LS1 4DL

First edition 2024

Editorial matter and selection © 2024 Rémy Herrera.

Individual chapters © 2024 The authors.

Published under exclusive licence by Emerald Publishing Limited.

Reprints and permissions service

Contact: www.copyright.com

No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, transmitted in any form or by any means electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise without either the prior written permission of the publisher or a licence permitting restricted copying issued in the UK by The Copyright Licensing Agency and in the USA by The Copyright Clearance Center. Any opinions expressed in the chapters are those of the authors. Whilst Emerald makes every effort to ensure the quality and accuracy of its content, Emerald makes no representation implied or otherwise, as to the chapters' suitability and application and disclaims any warranties, express or implied, to their use.

British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

ISBN: 978-1-80455-751-8 (Print)

ISBN: 978-1-80455-750-1 (Online)

ISBN: 978-1-80455-752-5 (Epub)

ISSN: 0161-7230 (Series)

About the Editor

Rémy Herrera (France) is an economist, researcher at the National Center of Scientific Research (CNRS). Graduated from a Business School (École supérieure de Commerce, 1988), the Institute of Political Studies (Institut d'Études politiques, 1990), and the University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne (Master of Philosophy, 1994; PhD in Economics, 1996), he supervises students in PhD at the Centre d'Économie de la Sorbonne. He started working in the financial audit (1988), at the OECD (1992–1997) and for the World Bank (1999–2000). He was member of the CNRS National Committee (2000–2005) and of the Scientific Council of Paris 1 (2001–2006). He taught at various universities in France (especially at Paris 1 [1993–2013]) and abroad, including at the Universities of Aleppo (1998), Cairo (1999–2000), Vitoria in Brazil (2006), Complutense in Madrid (2009–2013), and Lingnan in Hong Kong (2018). He was adviser to research programs at the Chubu University (Nagoya). He is or has been associated with: the Third World Forum (Dakar), the Union of Radical Political Economics (New York), the International Initiative for Promoting Political Economics (London), the Sociedad de Economía Política Latinoamericana (São Paulo), and the Asociación Nacional de Economistas de Cuba (Havana). He was the World Forum of Alternatives (WFA)'s Executive Secretary. He is also member of the Global University for Sustainability and of the International Crisis Observatory. He organizes the “Marx in the Twenty-First Century” seminar at La Sorbonne. He regularly works with the Centre Europe-Tiers Monde (Geneva), supporting it in its advisory role to the Human Rights Council of the United Nations.

About the Contributors

Joaquín Arriola (Spain) is a full Professor in the Department of Applied Economics at the University of the Basque Country (Spain). He has published various books, among them: Los Nuevos Países Industrializados (IEPALA, Madrid, 1988), Internacionalismo y Movimiento Obrero – El eje Norte-Sur (HOAC, Madrid, 1992; with P. Waterman), or La Globalización o la razón del más fuerte (Asociación Paz y Solidaridad de Asturias, Oviedo, 2011).

Juan Barredo-Zuriarrain (Spain) is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Applied Economics at the University of the Basque Country (Spain). He is also associate researcher at the Grenoble Research Center in Economics (University of Grenoble Alpes, France). He has published many articles in scientific reviews, including Structural Change and Economic Dynamics or New Political Economy.

William Paul Cockshott (United Kingdom) is a Scottish computer scientist and Marxist political economist. As a reader at the University of Glasgow, he has a BA in economics from Manchester University (1974), an MSc from Heriot Watt University (1976), and a PhD from University of Edinburgh (1982). He made significant contributions in computer science, as well as in economics, especially in the multidisciplinary area of economic computability. As the co-author of the book Towards a New Socialism (written with A. Cottrell), he advocates the use of cybernetics to build an efficient and democratic planning for a moneyless socialist economy.

Guido De Marco (Italy) is an independent researcher for the Association for the Redistribution of Labor in Rome. He holds a Master in Economics and was a Research Fellow of the Center for Economic Policy Analysis, New School for Social Research, as well as a PhD candidate at the New School for Social Research in 2001. He published “Fred Moseley, Money and Totality: A Macro-Monetary Interpretation of Marx's Logic in Capital and the End of the ‘Transformation Problem’” (Science & Society), “A Critique of Moseley's Money and Totality” (World Review of Political Economy), and “Marx's General Rate of Profit: How Turnover time, Accumulation and Rate of Surplus Value Affect the Formation of Prices of Production” (Capital & Class, forthcoming). His book, Marx and the Business, is currently under review.

Weinan Ding (China). She is a PhD student in economics at the School of Marxism of the Tsinghua University in Beijing, People's Republic of China. Her PhD dissertation deals with the evolution of the rate of profit in France in the long period. Her main research direction is Marxist economics. The profit rate and long wave theory are subjects of her ongoing research.

Demba Moussa Dembele (Senegal), economist-researcher, is member of the Council for the Development of Social Science Research in Africa (CODESRIA) and the Third World Forum (FTM). He holds a PhD in Financial Economics from the Pierre et Marie Curie University, Paris; MBA in international trade and finance from the American University (Washington D.C.). He was a former research associate at the Institute of International Finance (Washington D.C.). Currently, he is the Chair of the African Association for Research and Cooperation in Support of Endogenous Development (ARCADE).

Zhixuan Feng (China) is a Professor at the School of Economics and Management of the Wuhan University. He received his PhD in Economics from the School of Economics at the Renmin University of China in 2016. His current research interests are underdevelopment theory, mathematical political economy, and macroeconomics. He is also a specialist in input–output analysis.

Bangxi Li (China) is an Associate Professor (tenure) of political economy at the Institute of Economics, School of Social Sciences, of the Tsinghua University, Beijing, P.R. of China. His research interests include mathematical political economy, post-Keynesian economics, input–output analysis, and the Chinese economy. His representative publication is entitled Linear Theory of Fixed Capital and China's Economy: Marx, Sraffa and Okishio (Springer, 2017).

Zhiming Long (China), economist, is an Associate Professor at the School of Marxism at the Tsinghua University in Beijing. He supervises PhD since 2017 in this same institution. He is chair professor of Tang Scholar since 2018. He has a PhD in Economics from the University of Paris 1, as well as two Master’s degrees in economics from the University of Paris 1 and University of Paris 10. He is a specialist in growth theory, statistics, and (time-series analysis) econometrics.

Rosa Maria Marques (Brazil). Graduated from the University of Rio Grande do Sul (1974), the PUC-SP or Pontifícia Universidade Católica de São Paulo (1985), and the Getúlio Vargas Foundation (1996, PhD), with post-doctorates at the Universities of Grenoble (France) and of Buenos Aires (Argentine), she is a titular Professor in Economics at the PUC-SP. She is the former president of the Brazilian Society of Political Economy, member of the Brazilian Budget and Finance Commission of the National Council of Health, and President of the Brazilian Association of Health Economics.

Juan Pablo Mateo (Spain) is currently Associate Professor in the Department of Applied Economics, Structure & History, of the Complutense University of Madrid, and visiting scholar at the Institute for Research on World-Systems, in the University of California, Riverside (US). His research is focused on the theory of crisis, the tendency of the profit rate, and the core/periphery relation within the unequal development of world capitalism. His last book is The theory of crisis and the Great Recession in Spain (Palgrave, 2019), with articles in the Review of Radical Political Economics, Capital & Class, Science & Society, and International Review of Applied Economics, among others.

Ernesto Molina Molina (Cuba), doctor in Economic Sciences, is a member of Merit of the Academy of Sciences of Cuba. He is titular Professor of political economy, history of economic thought and economic theory at the Higher Institute of International Relations (Instituto Superior de Relaciones Internacionales Raúl Roa García). He is also the President of the Scientific Society of Economic Thought at the National Association of Economists and Accountants of Cuba (Asociación Nacional de Economistas y Contadores de Cuba).

Gustavo Moura de Cavalcanti Mello (Brazil), doctor in Sociology from the Universidade de São Paulo, post-doctorate in Sociology from the UNICAMP and in Economics from the Universidade de São Paulo, is a Professor of the Department of Economics and the Postgraduate Programme of Social Policy at the Universidade Federal do Espírito Santo (UFES) and a researcher at the National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq).

Paulo Nakatani (Brazil). As a graduate in economics from the Universities of Paraná (1971), Paris 10 Nanterre (1981), Picardie (1982, doctorate), and Paris 13 (2002, post-doctorate), he is a titular Professor in the Economics department and the Graduate Studies in Social Policy from the Universidade Federal do Espírito Santo, and collaborates with MST's Florestan Fernandes national school. He is the member of the editorial board of the review of the Brazilian Society of Political Economy, of which he was President, and member of the International Observatory of Crises.

Christian Palloix (France) is a Professor emeritus at the University of Picardie Jules Verne, Amiens (France). As a teacher in Economics, he was successively appointed at the Universities of Grenoble (1963–1977), Alger (1977–1978), Oran (1978–1981), and Amiens (1981–2005). As a researcher, he participated in the research centers of IREP-Grenoble (1967–1981), CRMSI-Paris (1981–1986), CRIISEA-Amiens (1987–2021, including as Director), LEFMI-Amiens (since 2021). His research focuses on globalization and multinational corporations, industrial economics and productive systems, labor economics, and development (notably Algeria).

Alfredo Saad-Filho (Brazil) is a Professor of Political Economy and International Development at King's College, London. Previously, he was a Professor at SOAS University of London, and senior economic affairs officer at the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). He has published extensively on neoliberalism, the political economy of development, industrial policy, climate adaptation, democracy, alternative economic policies, Latin America, inflation and stabilization, and the labor theory of value and its applications.

Mauricio de Souza Sabadini (Brazil), doctor in economics from the University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, is a Professor at the Department of Economics and the Postgraduate Programme of Social Policy at the Federal University of Espírito Santo (UFES). He is a researcher at the National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq) and Director (2016–2018), then president (2018–2020) of the Sociedade Brasileira de Economia Política.

Fabien Trémeau (France) is currently a PhD student at the University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne. He Graduated in philosophy and sociology from the University of Paris 4 Sorbonne and from the Institute of European Studies in Paris. His research focuses on the value and the commodity fetishism in Marx's work. As a publisher, he is also the Founder and Director of the Éditions Critiques.

Presentation

The new volume of Research in Political Economy that we deliver to the reader is devoted to the themes of value, money, profit, and capital within the theoretical and empirical framework of contemporary Marxism. To think about and discuss them, we brought together 18 economists – in addition to the author of these lines – from eight countries and four continents; economists who are, for some, experienced and internationally renowned personalities, and for others, young researchers starting their careers, but all working in their own way to broaden and deepen Marxism in order to apply its powerful methods to the interpretation and, above all, the transformation of the present world.

Even if we had to distinguish these four concepts of value, money, profit, and capital to better structure the exposition of the 13 contributions of the present volume, they are in fact narrowly related to each other in the analyzes provided by Marxism and its various currents. Let us briefly and basically recall here, in this presentation, how these distinct but linked notions are logically articulated by Marx and how they are dialectically chained in order to constitute the Marxian general theory of capitalist accumulation.

First, value: The law of value not only has the function of regulating exchanges but also commodity production and the reproduction of the capitalist system itself, based on private property. According to Marx, labor, as an expense of human power, is the source of value, determined by the labor time socially necessary for production. The commodity's dual character defines it, as we know, by both its use value, insofar as it has a social utility and satisfies human needs, and its exchange value, quantitative relation in which use values are exchanged for each other. Value in itself is the principle of this relation, lying on the labor crystallized in commodities, i.e., on what is common to all of them and allows them to be compared. Thus, the very substance of value resides in abstract labor, which is undifferentiated and noncomplex.

Secondly, money: The exchange relation involves money. If the commodity asserts itself as use value and in relation to another commodity as exchange value, the latter remains expressed with respect to the use value proper to this other good. Money brings commodities into relation under a common expression representing them as values, independently of the use values. The labor contained in them manifests itself as abstract labor. Extending the concept of value to the labor-power commodity leads to that of surplus value, key to the theory of exploitation. Observed in the fact of the capitalist's enrichment, surplus value is, as is known, an excess value produced by the wage earner, once reproduced the value of labor power, equivalent to salary. Unable to spring from an identity of value with itself, it arises from the process of production. Invisibilized under the appearance of free and equal exchanges of labor, it can only be identified at the level of global social labor because of the impossible distinction between the labor times devoted to the reproduction of value or to the production of value beyond the equivalent. The relation of exploitation, through the purchase of the use of labor power by the capitalist, is a monetary one. As value, the commodity is money, and its price is value in money form, fixed in its relation to a special “object,” both commodity and non-commodity, which embodies labor in general and serves as general equivalent.

Thirdly, profit: One of the “phenomenal” forms of the surplus value is – with money's interest, in particular – profit. As capitalism developed, a mode of production completely enclosed in the logic of money for money was propelled. The desire grew among capitalists to substitute commodities with money which, from a medium in exchanges, became a purpose in itself. Money acquired the property of functioning as capital, whose movement is only intended for profit. For Marx, profit is not a simple difference between income and expenditure, but results from the social organization of capitalism which polarizes the distribution of property rights. It is the form taken by the value form of the surplus labor, that is, the surplus value produced by the workers and extorted from them, according to the degree of exploitation of the labor power. Profit is a transformed form of surplus value, from which come all the income of the owners of capital. As an excess in money of commodity value over the production costs, it has a monetary form, implying the realization of commodities. Always for Marx, the rate of profit, or quotient of the surplus value to total advanced capital, is subject to laws, for some, spatial (intersectorial equalization under the effect of competition), for others, temporal (downward trend, stemming from a rising value composition of capital). Profit is born in the process of production, where surplus value is created, but is realized only in the process of circulation, from which seem to be drawn its commercial and banking parts, even more mystified forms of the “new value” than industrial profit. Fetishism in capitalist relations is such that profit seems to be generated from trade or even money itself. In the movement of capital, the extortion of social labor is concealed – just like the increasingly parasitic distribution of the conflictual fractions of profit.

And fourth, capital: Marx's determination of the concept of surplus value, which passes through the technical distinction between constant capital and variable capital, as sums of money, opens the way to the analysis of capital. The latter is the specific social relation of capitalist economy according to which value as valorization process is enhanced through the exploitation of labor. The exchange M – C, where the goals of use value and exchange value intertwine, can become a capitalist relationship M – C – Mʹ, where the accumulation of abstract wealth predominates. This social relation of capital is characterized by an inequality, because money is transformed into a commodity only with a view to the production of a higher quantity of value. As we have said, for Marx, a single commodity is indeed capable of producing a greater quantity of value; it is the labor power, which can produce more than its own value, since it daily works longer than the time required for its own production and thus contributes to capital's valorization. So we understand that capital does not exist without money. The term capital therefore also designates value itself in its process of self-valorization.

The four concepts of value, money, profit, and capital under consideration, being at the heart of all economic thought and its various problematics, constitute by this very fact major intellectual battlefields where the Marxist theoricians confront the many representatives of the mainstream in economics. As we unfortunately know too well, the striking dominance of the neoclassical mainstream is overwhelming today in academic institutions and their ideological apparatuses. Nevertheless, this hegemony, which is exercised to the detriment of all economic heterodoxies – and in the forefront of them Marxism – has in reality nothing of a scientific superiority, since the problems that neoclassicals encounter are numerous, serious, and so to speak insoluble when considering each of the four concepts we have chosen to examine. Let's take a closer look.

Contrary to the proponents of labor value who establish a distinction between value and price, these two notions are confused (“value-price”) for the neoclassicals. The theory of labor value certainly poses serious difficulties, in particular those of the heterogeneity of forms of labor not always being determined solely by time, of the existence of capital which represents past labor, of the taking into account of productive labor alone in the value's measure, or of the regulation of profits according to principles different from those of wages. To try to solve this last problem, linked to the transformation of values into prices, the neoclassicals decide to let the market take its course and do its thing, which led them not only to reject the labor value, but also to ignore the issue of value. The latter, for the mainstream, depends on the utility of the good and on the satisfaction provided to the one who holds this good. It then results from the confrontation of supply and demand, but, no longer distinguishing itself from the price, the neoclassicals cannot say anything about it. In this respect, it is symptomatic that Gérard Debreu, who founded with Kenneth Arrow and others the modern version of the general equilibrium theory, so to speak no longer used the term “value” beyond the introduction of his Theory of Value (1959).

Simultaneously a unit of account, an intermediary in exchanges and a means of reserve, money is accepted by all. Its property is to serve as a link between individuals, which supposes trust between them and with regard to the institution issuing it. However, a phenomenon such as trust is a matter of inter-individual relations, not of the behavior of agents taken in isolation; and the legal guarantee required of the State for its issuance and circulation in society requires the action of a network of institutions that cannot be reduced to individual choices. Money is a social and political link that connects individuals to each other and to a community in which they can identify. It comes that taking trust into account is a huge problem for the neoclassicals' methodological individualism giving primacy to the individual over society. It should be noted, by the way, that there is no money in their theoretical reference, the Arrow-Debreu model. Money is not a “neuter” tool, as the mainstream claims or as the expression “to make money work” suggests, forgetting that only human beings work. Money is not natural. It is a complex, contradictory social reality – just as inflation in an economy reflects the intensity of the class struggle inside that country. Money is power, an attribute of national sovereignty. Its common appropriation by the peoples conditions the control of their collective future.

Whereas, for Marx, as we have seen, all the value created finds its origin in labor and nowhere else, the neoclassicals, on the contrary, support the ideas that it also comes from capital, defined with them as an aggregate representing the whole inputs (with the notable exception of the labor “factor”) integrated in a “production function,” and that this capital “factor” is remunerated up to its contribution to production through profit, the “normal” counterpart of this created value. The neoclassicals nevertheless come up against a logical problem related to the definition of profit. Since the latter is conceived, for them, as the difference between income and expenses, and that these same expenditures are supposed to include the remuneration of all the factors that contribute to production, then such a difference can no longer remunerate anything more, thus certainly not capital. Hence a mainstream theory that leads to consider that profit is zero and this permanently or, in the best case, momentarily. Yet, zero profit is obviously not going to be very pleasant to hear or easy to accept by the capitalist entrepreneur. Anyway, the fact is that the neoclassicals do not provide a theoretical analysis of the capitalist entrepreneur either.

If, following Marx, the term “capital” refers to the specific type of exploitation of the capitalist system and designates a social relationship between the owners of the means of production and the wage earners, it is conceived very differently among the neoclassicals, as we have just seen. However, a big problem is attached to this aggregation method, because capital as a factor of production is not a single good, but a heterogeneous set. Here, the solution they propose is not one, since it consists in evaluating, thanks to a system of prices, each of the goods that make up this capital, then in adding the different numbers obtained so as to obtain a sum representative of the “capital.” And this is where the problem lies, because this unique number corresponds to a monetary “value,” and not to a physical entity, whereas the production function is supposed to represent only technical relations between the arguments that it integrates. The neoclassicals are consequently faced with the impossibility of calculating the prices of the production factors, including that of capital, by deriving them from the factorial marginal productivities, while determining the latter presupposes that their prices are known, including for capital.

In view of such difficulties encountered by the neoclassical mainstream, insurmountable by the methodologies it deploys, we understand that their current has no lesson in scientificity to give to Marxism. It is even the latter which, in our opinion, constitutes the most powerful scientific instrument of analysis today at our disposal to account for the complex evolutions of the world and above all to envisage and organize the social transformations aimed at emancipating the workers. This is what we will collectively strive to show in the contributions that follow. These cover a vast spectrum of current topics relating to capitalist globalization, going from changes in the monetary policy's instruments and objectives, the rise of the credit system and the mutations of money, transnational corporations and their strategic behavior in the competition specific to oligopolies, relocations and the decomposition of value chains to produce ever more segments in low-wage countries, trends in profit rates or the recent forms taken by unequal exchange, up to the current crisis of capital, financialization, fictitious capital and the accelerating fictitious movements of capital (including the credit system and money capital), the role of crypto-currencies, the possibilities of monetary regionalization, and, beyond all that, the opportunities for postcapitalist alternatives that are opening up before us.

Rémy Herrera, January 23, 2023