Optimal investment with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching

Hyo-Chan Lee (DATA ANALYTICS LAB Co., LTD., Seoul, Republic of Korea)
Seyoung Park (Nottingham University Business School, University of Nottingham, Nottingham, UK)
Jong Mun Yoon (Credit Finance Research Institute, Credit Finance Association of Korea, Seoul, Republic of Korea)

Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies: 선물연구

ISSN: 1229-988X

Article publication date: 4 June 2021

Issue publication date: 24 June 2021

551

Abstract

This study aims to generalize the following result of McDonald and Siegel (1986) on optimal investment: it is optimal for an investor to invest when project cash flows exceed a certain threshold. This study presents other results that refine or extend this one by integrating timing flexibility and changes in cash flows with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching. This study emphasizes that optimal thresholds are either overvalued or undervalued in the absence of time-varying transition probabilities. Accordingly, the stochastic nature of transition probabilities has important implications to the search for optimal timing of investment.

Keywords

Citation

Lee, H.-C., Park, S. and Yoon, J.M. (2021), "Optimal investment with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching", Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies: 선물연구, Vol. 29 No. 2, pp. 102-115. https://doi.org/10.1108/JDQS-12-2020-0032

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Hyo-Chan Lee, Seyoung Park and Jong Mun Yoon.

License

Published in Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies: 선물연구. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence maybe seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

An investor’s optimal investment decision is to invest when project cash flows exceed a certain threshold (McDonald and Siegel, 1986). Here, the investment decision resembles an American-style call option, where there exists the flexibility of choosing optimal timing of option exercise. Based on this analogy, we extend the standard real option approach to a regime-switching environment with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching and analyze the optimal investment decision [1].

Most real investment decisions have three important characteristics in varying degrees (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). First, the investment is partially or completely irreversible, i.e. investment cost incurred at investment time at least cannot be recovered. Second, the future cash flows from the investment are uncertain. Third, the timing of investment is flexible, i.e. an investor adjusts investment by an irreversible choice of investment time. In light of such investment characteristics, McDonald and Siegel (1986) also claim as follows:

The rule, “invest if the net present value of investing exceeds zero”, is only valid if the variance of the present value of future benefits and costs is zero or if the expected rate of growth of the present value is minus infinity; the value lost by following this suboptimal investment policy can be substantial.

This is precisely the direction we take here. We generalize this rule. Specifically, we generalize the McDonald and Siegel (1986) result to include regime switching (Guo et al., 2005; Bensoussan et al., 2012). By integrating timing flexibility and changes in cash flows with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching, we obtain regime-dependent optimal policies for investment. We hope that some results of this paper will lend themselves to the study of implications for real investment activities.

To examine the impact of macroeconomic conditions on optimal investment in the simplest possible environment, we assume that only two regimes exist, an increasing “Bull” market (regime B) and a decreasing “bear” market (regime b). Importantly, we consider a Markov regime switching model with time-varying transition probabilities (Diebold et al., 1994; Filardo, 1994). An investor would like to find the optimal timing of investment that gives the best profits in the long run taking into account that the transition probabilities between the two regimes vary over time. This is an optimal investment strategy that maximizes the expected profits of project cash flows that are governed by a two-state continuous-time Markov chain.

We present other results that refine or extend the result of McDonald and Siegel (1986) by integrating timing flexibility and changes in cash flows with time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching. We obtain regime-dependent optimal investment policies and reveal new insights into the implications of real investment activities when regimes can switch. We emphasize that optimal thresholds are either overvalued or undervalued in the absence of time-varying transition probabilities. Accordingly, the stochastic nature of transition probabilities has important implications to the search for optimal timing of investment.

2. Basic model

To examine the effect of macroeconomic conditions on optimal investment in the simplest possible environment, we assume that just two regimes, “Bull” (regime B) and “bear” (regime b), are possible. We also assume that regime i is observable and switches into regime j at the first jump time of a Poisson jump process with intensity λi > 0, for i,j ∈ {B,b}. The assumption of constant transition probabilities between two regimes (Guo et al., 2005; Bensoussan et al., 2012) is too restrictive to describe many empirical observations, such as asymmetric business-cycle features. To characterize the dynamics of regime switching better than the fixed-transition-probabilities version, we use a stochastic process for λi. Within the present model, the time Ti to leave regime i satisfies the following: for time t ≥ 0,

 Probability of {Ti>t}=10tλi,sds,   i{B,b},
where
(1) dλi,s=aiλi,sds+biλi,sdWsi,  λi,0=λi>0,  ai<0,  bi>0.

Here, Wsi for regime i ∈ {B,b} are standard one-dimensional and two independent Brownian motions. Ti is stochastic, so our model incorporates time-varying probabilities of transitions between two regimes. When we set ai = –λi and bi = 0, Ti follows an exponential distribution with intensity λi. This result implies the existence of probability λidt that regime i switches into regime j during an infinitesimal time interval dt. Further, the expected durations of regime switching are constant: the expected duration of regime i is 1/λi and the average fraction of time spent in regime i is λj/(λi + λj) . Therefore, the constant transition probabilities for regime switching can be regarded as a special case in our model.

To represent regime-dependent cash flows, we consider a stream of profit after taking a project as the following project cash flows Xt modeled by a geometric Brownian motion equipped with a two-state Markov regime switching model:

(2) dXt=μiXtdt+σiXtdWt,   X0=x>0,
where Wt is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion, i ∈ {B,b} is determined by a two-state continuous time Markov chain, μi > 0 is the expected rate of returns on project cash flows, and σi > 0 is the standard deviation of returns on cash flows, i.e. the volatility of project cash flows. Further, we assume that μB > μb and σb > σB. The project cash flows and the regime switching have asymmetric correlations in that dWt·dWti=ρidt for ρi ∈ [–1 1].

The presence of time-varying probabilities of transitions between two regimes directly affects the expected rate of returns on cash flows. The project cash flows Xt can be rewritten as (Appendix):

dXt=(μi+ρibiσi)Xtdt+σiXtdWti,Q
where Wti,Q is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion defined under the Q probability measure [2]. The economic intuition is straightforward. An investor encounters undiversifiable risk stemming from time-variation of regime intensity λi, which is well captured by the term involving Brownian motions Wsi in equation (1). Thus, the investor requires additional risk premia that are included in the expected rate of returns on cash flows. The risk premia can be positive or negative according to the sign of the correlations ρi. A negative correlation implies that investing in project cash flows could be a partial hedging tool for the unhedgeable risk of stochastic regime switching, and hence decreases the expected returns on cash flows.

An investor would like to find the optimal timing of investment that gives the best profits in the long run, taking into account that the transition probabilities between two regimes vary over time. This is an optimal investment strategy that maximizes the expected profits of project cash flows which are governed by a two-state continuous time Markov chain. More specifically, the optimal investment problem can be formulated as

maxτE[eδτ(Xτc)],
where δ > 0 is the appropriate discount rate, τ is optimal timing of investment, and c >* 0 is an investment cost. The investor owns an embedded option to invest that can only be exercised once, i.e. she can undertake the investment irreversibly at some optimally chosen time τ. The optimal timing of investment should be determined endogenously, so the investment time is stochastic from today’s perspective. The investor receives Xτc when she invests at some endogenously chosen time τ. She pays the investment cost c only at τ. We assume that this cost can be financed from the investor’s own wealth.

Following McDonald and Siegel (1986), the investor’s objective is to find a certain threshold of project cash flows over which it is optimal for the investor to undertake an irreversible investment. Most importantly, the endogenously determined threshold is not only regime dependent, but also significantly affected by the presence of time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching. Technically, we solve the optimal investment problem by using the variational inequality approach (Bensoussan and Lions, 1982; Øksendal, 2007). More specifically, in regime i = {B,b} we define ϕi(x) as the expected discounted payoff from the irreversible investment project undertaken at time τ and it is given by:

ϕi(x)=E[eδτ(Xτc)]

In regime i, the investor’s objective is to find an optimal stopping time τ to maximize the expected discounted payoff ϕi:

Φi(x)=maxr0ϕi(x)

3. Numerical results

We present graphical illustration and additional detail in discussion of our optimal investment strategy. To do this, we exploit regime-dependent optimal investment policies that are significantly affected by the presence of time-varying probabilities between two regimes (Appendix).

We set the baseline parameter values for numerical analysis as follows (Guo et al., 2005). We set appropriate discount rate δ = 0.06 [3]. The drift and volatility parameters of project cash flows during regime B are μB = 0.04 and σB = 0.2, and during regime b are μb = 0.01 and σb = 0.3. Our parameter choice for the drift and volatility reflects the fact that while volatility is higher in the bear market regime than in the Bull market regime, drift is higher in the Bull market regime than in the bear market regime (Ang and Bekaert, 2002). δ should be larger than the growth rates μi of project cash flows; otherwise, an investor never pays to invest, because the value of the investment opportunity is infinite (McDonald and Siegel, 1986). The parameters governing the persistence of regime chosen as follows: λB = 0.15 and λb = 0.1 [4]. Regarding the investment cost, we set c = 1 (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994) [5]. Finally, we set for the comparison purpose the volatility parameter bi of regime intensity λi to 0, i.e. we consider constant probabilities of transitions between two regimes. We will set bi to 0.1 in Figure 1 for consideration of time-varying regime transition probabilities.

3.1 Constant Transition probabilities

Table 1 reports the comparative statistics for regime-dependent optimal investment policies (x¯B,x¯b). The investment opportunity set that consists of the drift and volatility of project cash flows is not constant, and regimes B and b have fundamental parameters. This consideration of a stochastic investment opportunity set has a first-order effect on optimal investment strategies. Specifically, for the baseline parameter values, optimal timing of investment in regime B is faster than optimal timing in regime b, i.e. optimal thresholds x¯B in regime B are consistently smaller than those x¯b in regime b (Table 1).

An investor’s irreversible investment decision can be regarded as an American-style call option, where the investor has the flexibility of choosing the time of irreversible investment. The standard option pricing model shows that option value increases as market volatility increases. Also, the real option value for investment increases as project volatility increases, in the sense that increase in uncertainty causes increase in the value of an investor’s investment opportunities (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). As Dixit and Pindyck (1994) states:

Thus investment is highly sensitive to volatility in project values, irrespective of investors’ or managers’ risk preferences, and irrespective of the extent to which the riskiness of project values is correlated with the market.

Our results support the positive convexity effect of volatility on option value. The table confirms that regime-dependent optimal investment policies (x¯B,x¯b) increase with the volatility of any regime. Most importantly, the possibility of a regime switching means that the investor’s optimal strategy depends on the existence of the other regime. Specifically, the optimal strategy of investment timing is characterized by a different threshold in each regime. Due to the possibility of regime shift, each threshold incorporates the threshold in the other regime.

Changes in volatility in a given regime have major effects on investment thresholds of any state. For the baseline parameters, the thresholds are given a pair of (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.79,2.97). When the volatility of regime B is increased from 20% to 25%, the thresholds of any state also are raised by the amount (0.04,0.18), so (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.83,3.15). Similarly, when the volatility of regime b is increased from 30% to 35%, the thresholds of any state also are raised by the amount (0.35, 0.31), so (x¯B,x¯b)=(3.14,3.28). In this sense, we show monotonically increasing relations of optimal thresholds as the volatility of project cash flows increases.

Concerning the effects of varying drift rates of any regime, we show monotonically increasing relations of optimal thresholds as the drift of project cash flows increases. The rationale behind this result is that the expected appreciation in the value of an irreversible investment option rises as the expected rate of growth of project cash flows increases. As a result, waiting becomes cheaper than investing immediately. Further, changes in drift in a given regime have a large impact on investment thresholds of any state. For the baseline parameters, the thresholds are given as: (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.79,2.97). If the drift of regime B is raised by the amount 0.01; μB = 0.05, then thresholds of any state also are increased from (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.79,2.97) to (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.90,3.20). Similarly, if the drift of regime b is raised by the amount 0.003; μb = 0.013, then thresholds of any state also are increased from (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.79,2.97) to (x¯B,x¯b)=(2.91,3.08).

Optimal thresholds increase as discount rate δ decreases or as investment cost c increases. As expected, a decrease in δ increases the present value of expected project cash flows after investment decision, and hence increases the value of investment option, i.e. increases the opportunity cost of investing now. Accordingly, investment can be delayed as δ decreases. Of course, an increase in c raises the value of an investor’s investment option, and drives increase in the thresholds.

The functional dependence between regime-dependent optimal thresholds depends on the durations of regimes. Interestingly, the effects of varying the duration of a regime are asymmetric. A decrease of the persistence of regime B, i.e. an increase in λB reduces the opportunity cost of irreversible investment in regime B and hence lowers optimal threshold x¯B in regime B. One might wonder why investment in regime B can be hastened, because relatively frequent transition from regime B to regime b is expected. However, as persistence of regime B decreases, the expected appreciation in the value of investment option decreases, whereas the riskiness of project cash flows increases. To improve our understanding of the expected appreciation and the riskiness, we introduce regime-adjusted drift:

μ˜=λbλB+λbμB+λBλB+λbμb

and volatility as

σ˜=λbλB+λbσB+λBλB+λbσb
of project cash flows. When the parameter λB that governs the persistence of regime B is raised by 0.02 to λB = 0.17, then μ˜ decreases from 0.022 to 0.021, whereas σ˜ increases from 0.26 to 0.263. Accordingly, adjustments in the persistence of regime represent a trade-off between these two quantities, so the optimal thresholds depend crucially on μ˜ and σ˜. Combining all the effects, optimal thresholds can decrease when regime B is of shorter duration than regime b. In contrast, optimal thresholds can increase when regime B is of longer duration than regime b; this instance is well captured when λB decreases or λb increases.

3.2 Time-varying transition probabilities

To investigate the effects of time-varying probabilities of transitions between two regimes, we allow for the case where the volatility parameter bi i ∈ {B,b} of regime intensity λi is not zero. We set the volatility parameter bi to 0.1. Then we consider two symmetric correlations: ρB = ρb = 0.3 and ρB = ρb = –0.3. We will also consider asymmetric correlations supporting the existence of substantial heterogeneity across magnitudes of conditional correlations. The correlations between portfolios (or expected cash flows) tend to show a sharp increase which has been observed in the period of global financial crisis (2007–2009), which has turned out to contribute to contagion effects with the networks of interconnections that link individuals, financial institutions and firms with one another (Kim and Park, 2020) [6].

The presence of time-varying probabilities between two regimes has a significant effect on the regime-dependent optimal thresholds (Figure 1). We confirm that the optimal thresholds drift up as the drift and volatility parameters of project cash flows increase (Table 1 and Figure 1). One intriguing observation is that the optimal thresholds depend crucially on the current level of symmetric correlations ρi (i ∈ {B,b}). That is, the optimal thresholds drift upward as the current level of correlations increases. The economic intuition is that investing in project cash flows that have negative correlations with the regime switching could be a partial hedging tool against the unhedgeable or undiversifiable risk of stochastic regime switching, i.e. in such a case an investor requires negative risk premia. Then the negative correlation decreases the expected returns on cash flows, i.e. reduces the level of μi (i ∈ {B,b}). As a result, a negative and sizable correlation induces an investor to undertake the investment early. We emphasize that optimal thresholds from the comparative statistics (Table 1) are either overvalued or undervalued in the absence of time-varying transition probabilities. Accordingly, the stochastic nature of transition probabilities has important functions in the search for optimal timing of investment.

To contemplate the effects of asymmetric correlations on the optimal investment, we average the correlations across regime B and regime b by using the average fraction of time spent in each regime [7]:

ρ˜=λbλB+λbρB+λBλB+λbρb,
which is a regime-adjusted correlation just as regime-adjusted drift μ˜ and volatility σ˜. We then obtain asymmetric values of ρB and ρb by setting the regime-adjusted correlation to 0.3 and –0.3, having the two values of symmetric correlations used so far as a benchmark. We consider two asymmetric correlations: ρB = 0.15, ρb = 0.4 and ρB = –0.45, ρb = –0.2 [8].

In case of asymmetric correlations, the qualitative features of regime-dependent optimal thresholds with symmetric correlations remain unchanged (Figure 2), i.e. the optimal thresholds rise as the drift and volatility parameters of project cash flows increase.

4. Conclusion

In this paper, we develop an analytically tractable investment model by generalizing McDonald and Siegel (1986)’s investment framework to include time-varying transition probabilities for regime switching. Consistent with the canonical investment framework, we also discover the existence of a certain threshold of cash flows over which it is optimal for an investor to invest in a new project. However, using this threshold for investment without taking into account time-varying transition probabilities represents an over-simplified situation, i.e. optimal investment thresholds are either overestimated or underestimated in the absence of time-varying transition probabilities. Therefore, neglecting the stochastic nature of transition probabilities can be costly to the investor who aims to make the optimal investment decision.

Figures

Regime-dependent optimal thresholds (symmetric correlations)

Figure 1.

Regime-dependent optimal thresholds (symmetric correlations)

Regime-dependent optimal thresholds (asymmetric correlations)

Figure 2.

Regime-dependent optimal thresholds (asymmetric correlations)

Comparative statistics for (x¯B,x¯b)

Parameters The riskiness of project cash flows
Volatility of regime B Volatility of regime b
2(0%) 25(0%) 30(0%) 30(0%) 35(0%) 40(0%)
Base parameter (2.79, 2.97) (2.83, 3.15) (2.88, 3.38) (2.79, 2.97) (3.14, 3.28) (3.53, 3.62)
μB = 0.04 −0.01 (2.69, 2.75) (2.74, 2.91) (2.79, 3.12) (2.69, 2.75) (3.03, 3.02) (3.40, 3.32)
−0.005 (2.74, 2.86) (2.78, 3.03) (2.84, 3.25) (2.74, 2.86) (3.08, 3.15) (3.46, 3.47)
+0.005 (2.84, 3.08) (2.89, 3.28) (2.94, 3.51) (2.84, 3.08) (3.21, 3.41) (3.61, 3.77)
+0.01 (2.90, 3.20) (2.94, 3.40) (2.99, 3.64) (2.90, 3.20) (3.28, 3.54) (3.69, 3.93)
μb = 0.01 −0.003 (2.68, 2.87) (2.72, 3.05) (2.76, 3.25) (2.68, 2.87) (3.01, 3.16) (3.38, 3.49)
−0.0015 (2.73, 2.92) (2.78, 3.10) (2.83, 3.32) (2.73, 2.92) (3.08, 3.22) (3.46, 3.55)
+0.0015 (2.85, 3.03) (2.89, 3.21) (2.95, 3.44) (2.85, 3.03) (3.21, 3.34) (3.61, 3.69)
+0.003 (2.91, 3.08) (2.96, 3.27) (3.01, 3.50) (2.91, 3.08) (3.28, 3.41) (3.69, 3.76)
δ = 0.06 −0.005 (2.97, 3.20) (3.02, 3.40) (3.08, 3.65) (2.97, 3.20) (3.37, 3.55) (3.80, 3.93)
−0.025 (2.87, 3.08) (2.92, 3.27) (2.98, 3.50) (2.87, 3.08) (3.25, 3.40) (3.66, 3.77)
+0.025 (2.71, 2.88) (2.75, 3.05) (2.80, 3.27) (2.71, 2.88) (3.05, 3.17) (3.42, 3.49)
+0.005 (2.64, 2.79) (2.68, 2.96) (2.73, 3.17) (2.64, 2.79) (2.96, 3.07) (3.32, 3.37)
c = 1 −0.5 (1.39, 1.49) (1.42, 1.58) (1.44, 1.69) (1.39, 1.49) (1.57, 1.64) (1.76, 1.81)
−0.25 (2.09, 2.23) (2.12, 2.36) (2.16, 2.53) (2.09, 2.23) (2.36, 2.46) (2.65, 2.71)
+0.25 (3.48, 3.71) (3.54, 3.94) (3.61, 4.22) (3.48, 3.71) (3.93, 4.10) (4.41, 4.52)
+0.5 (4.18, 4.46) (4.25, 4.73) (4.33, 5.07) (4.18, 4.46) (4.71, 4.92) (5.29, 5.43)
λB = 0.15 −0.02 (2.80, 3.01) (2.85, 3.22) (2.90, 3.47) (2.80, 3.01) (3.15, 3.31) (3.54, 3.64)
−0.01 (2.79, 2.99) (2.84, 3.18) (2.89, 3.42) (2.79, 2.99) (3.14, 3.29) (3.53, 3.63)
+0.01 (2.78, 2.95) (2.83, 3.13) (2.88, 3.34) (2.78, 2.95) (3.14, 3.26) (3.53, 3.61)
+0.02 (2.78, 2.94) (2.82, 3.10) (2.87, 3.31) (2.78, 2.94) (3.13, 3.25) (3.53, 3.60)
λb = 0.1 −0.01 (2.77, 2.95) (2.82, 3.12) (2.86, 3.33) (2.77, 2.95) (3.13, 3.26) (3.52, 3.61)
−0.005 (2.78, 2.96) (2.82, 3.14) (2.87, 3.36) (2.78, 2.96) (3.14, 3.27) (3.53, 3.61)
+0.005 (2.79. 2.98) (2.84. 3.17) (2.90, 3.40) (2.79, 2.98) (3.15, 3.29) (3.53, 3.62)
+0.01 (2.80. 2.99) (2.85. 3.18) (2.91, 3.42) (2.80, 2.99) (3.15, 3.29) (3.54, 3.63)
Notes:

The baseline parameter values are fixed as follows: discount rate δ = 0.06, drift and volatility parameters of project cash flows in regime B are μB = 0.04 and σB = 0.2, drift and volatility parameters in regime b are μb = 0.01 and σb = 0.3, parameters governing the persistence of regime are λB = 0.15 and λb = 0.1, investment cost c = 1

Notes

1.

The real option approach has had a lot of applications in many areas of quantitative management with interest in operations management and finance/economics. Recently, Kang and Han (2020) have applied the real option theory to a military service system.

2.

Q is the probability measure that has the following relationship with the physical probability measure P:

dQ=ebiWti12bi2tdP.

Please refer to Appendix for more technical details and derivations.

3.

In this paper, a time discount rate of δ is assumed to be constant, rather than regime dependent. Our paper focus is on the effects of regime-dependent changes in project cash flows with time-varying regime transition probabilities, thereby abstracting away complex issues of other parameters. In this paper, the drift and volatility of the project cash flows do change across regimes (Ang and Bekaert, 2002), maintaining the discount rate constant. We fully acknowledge that the time discount rate could be regime dependent, which may significantly affect the optimal policies. Such changes in the discount rate (or the preference parameters), however, are known to give rise to considerable challenges in solving optimal investment problems because the principle of dynamic programming is no longer applicable. For the purpose of simplicity and tractability as in a large body of literature on regime switching (Hackbarth et al., 2006; Jang et al., 2007; Park, 2018; Kim et al., 2021), we decide to use a constant as the discount rate. To address any concerns that the discount rate is merely constant, we vary it in Table 1 and partially observe the effects of changes in the discount rate on the optimal strategies.

4.

The expected durations of a Bull regime and a bear regime are 1/λB and 1/λb, respectively. As a result, the bear market regime lasts longer than the Bull market regime. To reflect the empirical reality that the Bull market regime typically lasts longer than the bear market regime, λb could be higher than λB, which has been considered in Table 1.

5.

We focus on the effects of regime-dependent project cash flows in the simplest possible economic setup, thereby neglecting the effects of time-varying investment cost. The investment cost could be a constant ratio to the expected cash flow at the time of optimal investment or some other size of investment. Even though the investment cost is constant, the optimal investment time determined in this paper is still stochastic from today’s perspective. The constant investment cost is chosen purely for analytical convenience following the literature on investment (Miao and Wang, 2007).

6.

The correlation fluctuations have been considered in investment models (Buraschi et al., 2010). More recently, Kim et al. (2021) have incorporated in their investment model sector-level investment with correlation fluctuations by namely dynamic and asymmetric correlations between industry and market portfolios. In addition to the time-varying and regime-dependent investment opportunity, we consider in our investment model asymmetric correlations between portfolios (or expected cash flows).

7.

With regime intensities, λB and λb, the regime B lasts on average 1/λB and the regime b lasts on average 1/λb. The average fraction of time spent in the regime B and the regime b is then given by λb/(λB+λb) and λB/(λB+λb), respectively.

8.

In any case of asymmetric correlations, the chosen parameter values reflect the fact that the correlation in the regime b is inclined to be larger than that in the regime B, contributing to contagion effects at times of economic recessions.

Appendix

In this appendix, we derive optimal timing of investment selected by an investor. We obtain regime-dependent optimal investment policies that are significantly affected by the presence of time-varying probabilities of transitions between two regimes. The optimal investment is characterized by two regions: a continuation region in which the investor’s optimal choice is to delay an irreversible investment project; and a stopping region in which she should undertake the investment.

Prior to moving on the technical details behind the optimal investment strategies with time-varying regime transition probabilities in Section 3. Numerical Results, we recall some notations used in Section 2. The Basic Model.

The time Ti to leave regime i ∈ {B,b} satisfies the following: for time t ≥ 0:

 Probability of{Ti>t}=10tλi,sds
where
dλi,s=aiλi,sds+biλi,sdWsi,  λi,0=λi>0,  ai<0,  bi>0

Here, Wsi for regime i ∈ {B,b} are standard one-dimensional and two independent Brownian motions.

We consider a stream of profit after taking a project as the following project cash flows Xt:

dXt=μiXtdt+σiXtdWt,  X0=x>0
where Wt is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion, i is determined by a two-state continuous time Markov chain with B identifying the “Bull” state and b identifying the “bear” one, μi > 0 is the expected returns on project cash flows, and σi > 0 is the standard deviation of returns on cash flows, i.e. the volatility of project cash flows. The project cash flows and the regime switching have the asymmetric correlations in the sense that dWt·dWti=ρidt for ρi ∈ [–1,1].

The optimal investment problem can be formulated as the following:

maxrE[eδτ(Xτc)]
where δ > 0 is the appropriate discount rate, τ is optimal timing of investment, and c >* 0 is an investment cost.

Theorem. It is optimal for an investor to invest when project cash flows exceed regime-dependent thresholds x¯i in regime i (i ∈{B,b}).

Proof. The investor’s objective function is rewritten by an integral form. Specifically, the assumption of the time Ti to leave regime i in which regime intensity λi is formulated by a geometric Brownian motion yields:

Φi(x)=maxτ0E[eδτ(Xτc)]=maxτ0E[0τλi,seδτΦj(Xs)ds+(10τλi,sds)eδτ(Xτc)]=maxτ0EQ[0τe(λi+δ)tλiΦj(Xt)dt+e(λi+δ)τ(Xτc)],
where Q is the probability measure that has the following relationship with the physical probability measure P:
dQ=ebiWti12bi2tdP.

Here, we set the drift parameter ai of regime intensity λi to –λi,0 = –λi . By the Girsanov’s theorem:

Wti,QWtρibit
is a Brownian motion under the Q probability measure. Then the cash flows process (2) is restated as:
dXt=μiXtdt+σiXt(dWti,Q+ρibidt)=(μi+ρibiσi)Xtdt+σiXtdWti,Q

Notice that the presence of time-varying transition probabilities increases or decreases the expected rate of returns on project cash flows, according to the sign of correlations ρi and the magnitude of the volatility parameters bi and σi of regime intensity λi and cash flows Xt, respectively.

According to the connection between the optimal stopping problem and variational inequality (Bensoussan and Lions, 1982; Øksendal, 2007), we obtain the following variational inequality: for any x > 0 and i,j ∈ {B,b}:

(3) {12x2σi2Φi(x)(μi+ρibiσi)xΦi(x)+δΦi(x)λi(Φj(x)Φi(x))0,Φi(x)xc,[12x2σi2Φi(x)(μi+ρibiσi)xΦi(x)+δΦi(x)λi(Φj(x)Φi(x))][Φi(x)(xc)]=0

The strict inequality and equality in the first inequality in equation (3) hold in the stopping region and the continuation region, respectively. Further, the strict inequality in the second inequality in equation (3) represents the case where the investor’s objective function Φ prior to investment is strictly larger than the payoff from the irreversible investment project. Accordingly, in this case the investor is in the continuation region and optimally delays the investment decision. When her objective function Φ approaches the payoff from the investment, the investor is in the stopping region and hence she undertakes the investment project. Notice that the third equality in equation (3) is required because of the fact that for any x >* 0, one of the first two inequalities in equation (3) must hold.

We show that the optimal investment problem is solved by finding regime-dependent stopping boundaries i.e. free boundaries x¯i, which should be determined by value-matching and smooth-pasting conditions. The problem is formulated as follows: for i,j ∈ {B,b}:

(4) {12x2σi2Φi(x)(μi+ρibiσi)xΦi(x)+δΦi(x)λi(Φj(x)Φi(x))=0,   0<x<x¯iΦi(x)=xc,   xx¯i

As the expected discounted payoff ϕi is strictly increasing in x and the fact that μB > μb and σb > σB, it is straightforward to show that x¯b>x¯B. Then the problem (4) can be restated as the following system of differential equations:

(5) {12x2σi2Φi(x)(μi+ρibiσi)xΦi(x)+δΦi(x)λi(Φj(x)Φi(x))=0,   0<x<x¯i,Φb(x¯b)=x¯bc,   Φb(x¯b)=1,ΦB(x¯B)=x¯Bc,   ΦB(x¯B)=1.

The value-matching condition imposes an equality at x¯i between the objective functions Φi and the payoff from the irreversible investment project. Moreover, the functions Φi should be piecewise C2 because project cash flows follow a (piecewise) continuous Borel-bounded function (Karatzas and Shreve, 1991). The functions Φi satisfies the continuity and smoothness and hence the smooth-pasting condition imposes an equality at x¯i between the first derivatives of Φi and xc taken with respect to x.

The system (5) can be solved up to closed-from expressions for endogenously chosen timing of investment which is characterized by regime-dependent stopping boundaries x¯i over which it is optimal for an investor to undertake an investment in regime i. More specifically, we obtain the following explicit solutions for the objective functions Φb and ΦB:

(6) Φb(x)=Abxβb+ABxβB,   0<x<x¯B,ΦB(x)=Bbxβb+BBxβB,   0<x<x¯B,ΦB(x)=CxαB+C*xαB*+λb(xc)λb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb),   x¯B<x<x¯b
where αi > 1 and αi*<0 are the two roots to the following characteristic equation:
CEi(n)=12σi2n(n1)(μi+ρibiσi)n+δ+λi=0,   i{B,b},
and βb and βB (1 < βb < αi < βB) are the two roots to the following equation:
CEb(n)CEB(n)=λbλB.

Using the explicit solutions proposed by equation (6) and piecewise C2 condition of Φi with value-matching and smooth-pasting conditions given in equation (5), we derive:

(7) {Ab(x¯B)βb+AB(x¯B)βB=x¯Bc,βbAb(x¯B)βb1+βBAB(x¯B)βB1=1,C(x¯b)αB+C*(x¯b)αB*+λb(x¯bc)λb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb)=x¯bc,αBC(x¯b)αB1+αB*C*(x¯b)αB*1+λbλb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb)=1,Bb(x¯B)βb+BB(x¯B)βB=C(x¯B)αB+C*(x¯B)αB*+λb(x¯Bc)λb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb),βbBb(x¯B)βb1+βBBB(x¯B)βB1=αBC(x¯B)αB1+αB*C*(x¯B)αB*1+λbλb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb).

Furthermore, for 0<x<x¯B substituting the explicit solutions in equation (6) into the first equation in equation (5) yields the following relationships between Ai and Bi:

(8) Bb=λBCEB(βb)Ab   and   BB=λBCEB(βB)AB.

Note that we have six unknown constants (Ab or Bb,AB or BB,C,C*,x¯b,x¯B) and six equations associated with the constants in equation (7). After a little simple calculation gives the following expressions for Ab, AB, C, and C* in terms of x¯b and x¯B:

(9) Ab=(βB1)x¯BβBc(βBβb)(x¯B)βb,   AB=(βb1)x¯Bβbc(βbβB)(x¯B)βB,C=(δ(μb+ρbbbσb))(αB*αB)(λb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb))(x¯b)αB((αB*1)x¯bαB*c),C*=(δ(μb+ρbbbσb))(αBαB*)(λb+δ(μb+ρbbbσb))(x¯b)αB*((αB1)x¯bαBc).

According to the relationships given in equation (9), if two free boundaries x¯b and x¯B are determined, then the four constants of (Ab, AB, C, C*) also are automatically determined. Using the relationships (8) between Ai and Bi and substituting the four constants in equation (9) into the last two equations in equation (7), we can determine x¯b and x¯B, numerically. Q.E.D.

References

Ang, A. and Bekaert, G. (2002), “International asset allocation with regime shifts”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 1137-1187.

Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J.L. (1982), Applications of Variational Inequalities in Stochastic Control, North Holland.

Bensoussan, A., Yao, Z.F. and Yin, G. (2012), “Threshold-type policies for real options using regime-switching models”, SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 667-689.

Buraschi, A., Porchia, P. and Trojani, F. (2010), “Corrleation risk and optimal portfolio choice”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 65 No. 1, pp. 393-420.

Diebold, F.X., Lee, J.-H. and Weinbach, G. (1994), Regime Switching with Time-Varying Transition Probabilities. Nonstationary Time Series Analysis and Cointegration, Advanced Texts in Econometrics, Granger, C.W.J. and Mizon, G. (Eds), Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 283-302.

Dixit, A. and Pindyck, R. (1994), Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

Filardo, A.J. (1994), “Business-cycle phases and their transitional dynamics”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 299-308.

Guo, X., Miao, J. and Morellec, E. (2005), “Irreversible investment with regime shifts”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 122 No. 1, pp. 37-59.

Hackbarth, D., Miao, J. and Morellec, E. (2006), “Capital structure, credit risk, and macroeconomic conditions”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 82 No. 3, pp. 519-550.

Jang, B.-G., Koo, H.K., Liu, H. and Loewenstein, M. (2007), “Liquidity premia and transaction costs”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 62 No. 5, pp. 2329-2366.

Kang, H.-G. and Han, B. (2020), “An option embedded novel military service system based on cognitive bias theories”, Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies, Vol. 28, pp. 141-148.

Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S. (1991), Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd ed., Springer.

Kim, J. and Park, Y.J. (2020), “Contagion between liquid and illiquid assets during the financial crisis: evidence from the US credit derivative market”, Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies, Vol. 28, pp. 107-122.

Kim, M.H., Park, S. and Yoon, J.M. (2021), “Industry portfolio allocation with asymmetric correlations”, The European Journal of Finance, Vol. 27 Nos 1/2, pp. 178-198.

McDonald, R. and Siegel, D. (1986), “The value of waiting to invest”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 101 No. 4, pp. 707-728.

Miao, J. and Wang, N. (2007), “Investment, consumption, and hedging under incomplete markets”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86 No. 3, pp. 608-642.

Øksendal, B. (2007), Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduction with Applications, 5th ed., Springer.

Park, S. (2018), “A generalization of Ramsey rule on discount rate with regime switching”, Economics Letters, Vol. 170, pp. 147-150.

Acknowledgements

The research of the second author (Seyoung Park) was supported by the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2019S1A5A2A03054249).

Corresponding author

Seyoung Park can be contacted at: seyoung.park@nottingham.ac.uk

Related articles