Abstract
Purpose
This survey explores the application of real options theory to the field of health economics. The integration of options theory offers a valuable framework to address these challenges, providing insights into healthcare investments, policy analysis and patient care pathways.
Design/methodology/approach
This research employs the real options theory, a financial concept, to delve into health economics challenges. Through a systematic approach, three distinct models rooted in this theory are crafted and analyzed. Firstly, the study examines the value of investing in emerging health technology, factoring in future advantages, associated costs and unpredictability. The second model is patient-centric, evaluating the choice between immediate treatment switch and waiting for more clarity, while also weighing the associated risks. Lastly, the research assesses pandemic-related government policies, emphasizing the importance of delaying decisions in the face of uncertainties, thereby promoting data-driven policymaking.
Findings
Three different real options models are presented in this study to illustrate their applicability and value in aiding decision-makers. (1) The first evaluates investments in new technology, analyzing future benefits, discount rates and benefit volatility to determine investment value. (2) In the second model, a patient has the option of switching treatments now or waiting for more information before optimally switching treatments. However, waiting has its risks, such as disease progression. By modeling the potential benefits and risks of both options, and factoring in the time value, this model aids doctors and patients in making informed decisions based on a quantified assessment of potential outcomes. (3) The third model concerns pandemic policy: governments can end or prolong lockdowns. While awaiting more data on the virus might lead to economic and societal strain, the model emphasizes the economic value of deferring decisions under uncertainty.
Practical implications
This research provides a quantified perspective on various decisions in healthcare, from investments in new technology to treatment choices for patients to government decisions regarding pandemics. By applying real options theory, stakeholders can make more evidence-driven decisions.
Social implications
Decisions about patient care pathways and pandemic policies have direct societal implications. For instance, choices regarding the prolongation or ending of lockdowns can lead to economic and societal strain.
Originality/value
The originality of this study lies in its application of real options theory, a concept from finance, to the realm of health economics, offering novel insights and analytical tools for decision-makers in the healthcare sector.
Keywords
Citation
de Mello-Sampayo, F. (2024), "Strategic flexibility in healthcare: an exploration of real options", Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 51 No. 9, pp. 177-199. https://doi.org/10.1108/JES-10-2023-0605
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Felipa de Mello-Sampayo
License
Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
Health economics operates within an environment characterized by uncertainty, in which decision-makers face various risks and unknown outcomes. Traditional economic models often struggle to capture the complexities of decision-making under uncertainty. The decisions should be based on expected net benefit (NB), so that when comparing mutually exclusive treatment strategies for a particular disease, the optimal strategy is simply the one with the greatest expected NB (Claxton, 1999). Nevertheless, decisions based on expected NB are appropriate only if there is also some consideration of whether current evidence is sufficient for allocating health-care resources, based on an assessment of the consequences of decision uncertainty. If the decision uncertainty and the consequences of adopting a suboptimal strategy are large, the decision-maker may wish for additional evidence on which to base the adoption decision (Sculpher and Claxton, 2005). This article explores the application of real options theory as developed by Dixit and Pindyck (1994), in healthcare decision-making, examining its implications for healthcare investments, policy analysis, and patient outcomes.
Options theory is a branch of finance that focuses on valuing and analyzing financial derivatives known as options. Options provide the holder with the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell an underlying asset at a predetermined price within a specified time period. Dixit and Pindyck (1994) expanded options theory to address the complexities of economic decision-making under uncertainty. They recognized that economic agents face uncertain future outcomes and have the flexibility to make strategic choices based on evolving market conditions. Their approach allows for evaluating the value of project opportunities, taking into account the flexibility to exercise or delay projects based on uncertain outcomes. Real options analysis captures the value of waiting, abandoning, or expanding projects, providing a more accurate assessment of economic decision-making.
Real options theory provides an assessment of the value of investing in medical technologies, research and development, infrastructure, and capacity expansion (Palmer and Smith, 2000). By incorporating the flexibility to exercise or delay the option to invest based on uncertain outcomes, it provides a more accurate assessment of the value of healthcare investments. Here, there is special focus on Technology Assessment, since it evaluates the value of adopting new medical technologies, considering the flexibility to exercise or delay adoption based on evolving evidence and market conditions. This approach provides a more comprehensive understanding of the economic value and impact of new healthcare technologies (Fornaro et al., 2021).
The real options theory framework can also be applied to the analysis of patient outcomes under uncertainty. It allows for the evaluation of treatment options, considering the flexibility to adapt treatments based on evolving patient conditions and uncertain outcomes. By incorporating the value of waiting, switching treatments, or exploring alternative therapies, it provides insights into optimal patient care pathways and resource allocation (Driffield and Smith, 2007). Uncertainty plays a significant role in healthcare policy choices. Real options theory assesses the value of policy flexibility and the impact of uncertain policy changes on health outcomes and healthcare costs (Attema et al., 2010). It helps to determine the optimal timing and design of policies, such as insurance reforms, healthcare regulations, and public health interventions, accounting for the strategic behavior of stakeholders.
Three different real options models are presented in this study to illustrate their applicability and value in aiding decision-makers to assess investment opportunities, medical decisions, and public health decisions. The first model is applied to investment in a new technology, and by inputting potential future benefits, discount rates, and the variability (volatility) of these benefits, the model can help to assess the value of the option. In the second model a patient has the option of switching treatments now or waiting for more information before optimally switching treatments. However, waiting has its risks, such as disease progression. By modeling the potential benefits and risks of both options and factoring in the time value, the model aids doctors and patients in making informed decisions based on a quantified assessment of potential outcomes. In the third model, a government has the option to leave lockdown during an ongoing pandemic. Alternatively, they can wait for more information about the virus, but incur the risk of the negative effects that the lockdown measures have on the economy and social well-being. The theoretical model argues that in the presence of uncertainty the possibility of deferring the decision until some later time when better information may become available has an economic value. By delaying it can provide a quantified assessment of whether to leave lockdown now or wait, helping policymakers make evidence-based decisions. Thus, by incorporating strategic behavior and options analysis, the real options approach offers valuable insights into healthcare investments, policy formulation, and patient outcomes. One can make more-informed assessments and recommendations, leading to improved decision-making and outcomes in the ever evolving field of healthcare.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the literature that has applied real options to healthcare decision-making. Section 3 puts forward three formal real options models applied to the healthcare sector. Section 4 examines the implications of the real options approach for healthcare decision-making. Concluding comments are in Section 5.
2. Real options theory in health economics
This section provides an overview of the adaptation of real options theory to the healthcare decision-making. Several studies demonstrate the application of real options analysis across various aspects of healthcare decision-making, encompassing investment evaluations, treatment strategies, cost-effectiveness assessments, and the optimization of vaccination programs, among others.
There are two seminal manuscripts that apply real options theory in healthcare. Palmer and Smith (2000) used a cost-benefit framework, introducing the concept of net social benefit (NSB) to evaluate investments in healthcare technologies, which had not been previously explored; and Driffield and Smith (2007) conducted the first study to apply real options theory in medical decision-making. The authors applied real options theory to the concept of watchful waiting, demonstrating how real options analysis can guide decisions regarding when to pursue a watchful waiting strategy for specific patients.
Following Palmer and Smith (2000), who analyze healthcare technologies using the cost-benefit framework and the concept of net social benefit, there is a group of studies that focus on analyzing investments in machines, technologies, pharmaceuticals stocks, health insurance plans, public health initiatives, new treatments, infrastructure, and health systems. These studies represent traditional applications of real options, wherein investors analyze whether investing their capital in a particular project yields returns that are expected to be greater than the company’s cost of capital. Smyth and Swinand (2002) apply real options theory to evaluate capital investment opportunities, capturing the value of flexibility. They emphasize that managerial flexibility is particularly valuable in high-risk investment opportunities. (Williams et al., 2007) discuss the application of real options to support investment decisions for a hospital’s new imaging department. (Levaggi and Michele, 2004) analyze optimal investment decisions in new healthcare technologies in uncertain environments. Pertile (2008) uses real options theory to analyze the timing of investment in new technologies by healthcare providers, considering competition for patients and alternative payment systems. Pertile et al. (2009) present an economic evaluation from a hospital’s perspective on the investment in positron emission tomography (PET). Levaggi et al. (2009) employ a real options framework to evaluate investments in new technologies and Pertile (2009) incorporates option values into the economic evaluation of PET.
Following Driffield and Smith (2007), the group of studies addressing watchful waiting and switching patient therapies aids physicians in deciding whether to initiate treatment immediately or delay it until a future time. This approach incorporates the patient’s health condition as part of the risk equation. The authors highlight the potential benefits of postponing decisions to gather more relevant information and avoid irreversible or risky treatments. When analyzing situations in which current treatment decisions have irreversible implications for the treatment of future diseases, and decision-makers are choosing between competing interventions with differing temporal consequences, Zivin and Neideill (2009) find that irreversibility raises the value of treatment modalities that preserve future treatment options. However, introducing some reversibility can either increase or decrease the option’s value, depending on the distribution of patient types. These authors also examine the relationship between option values and the biological and economic parameters that characterize any given set of technologies. Grutters et al. (2011) examine the adoption of proton therapy compared to stereotactic body radiotherapy for the treatment of inoperable stage I non-small cell lung cancer. Meyer and Rees (2012) analyze the treatment decision at a general level. They determine optimal threshold values for initiating the intervention, and derive comparative statics results with respect to the model parameters. In particular, an increase in the degree of uncertainty over the patient’s health state makes waiting more attractive in most cases. However, this may not hold if the patient’s health state has a tendency to improve. Forster and Pertile (2013a) use real options theory to decide whether to adopt a new health technology instead of an existing one in patient treatment. de Mello-Sampayo (2015) explores the timing of switching to second-line antiretroviral therapy (ART) under health uncertainty and in the absence of viral load monitoring. de Mello-Sampayo (2022) finds that under irreversibility of time spent in treatment, low-risk patients must use teledermatology as soon as possible, which is precisely when it is least valuable.
Related to public health decision-making, Attema et al. (2010) apply real options theory to assess the value of stockpiling antiviral drugs as a precautionary measure against potential influenza pandemics. Their analysis incorporates the option to defer action. Favato et al. (2012) apply the payoff method to determine the real options values of four different human papillomavirus vaccination (HPV) strategies. According to the authors the payoff method offers distinct advantages in assessing the cost-effectiveness of competing healthcare interventions. Pertile et al. (2014) present a Bayesian sequential economic evaluation model for health technologies, allowing flexibility in the decisions regarding the timing to cease research. Park (2016) analyzes the optimal vaccination strategy for pandemic diseases, considering the stochastic diffusion process of the disease.
Real options theory has been applied in other areas of healthcare. Sengupta and Kreier (2011) develop a dynamic framework for analyzing individual choices between Preferred Provider Organizations (PPOs) and Health Maintenance Organizations (HMOs) using real options theory. Their approach evaluates the benefits and flexibility associated with different healthcare provider options. Smith and Yip (2016) highlight the importance of option pricing theory in developing treatable methods that address the complexity and interconnectedness of health systems. Regardless of whether the real options concept is applied to patient treatment, public health strategy analyses, investment analyses, or other areas, the central idea remains consistent: reducing uncertainty pertaining to decisions made at present.
Finally, Smith (2007) evaluates the value of option contracts that provide the right to use specific drugs in the future. This analysis focuses on the option value and the potential future health benefits. This type of option assists decision-makers in managing risks arising from uncertainties surrounding health conditions and treatment availability. More recently, (Garrison et al., 2017) emphasize the significance of considering real options in cost-effectiveness analyses and Lakdawalla et al. (2018) demonstrate that real options are considered an essential element in healthcare value assessment. The fundamental objective underlying these operations is to reduce future uncertainty and maximize results, such as saving patients’ lives, extending their life expectancy, or improving survival conditions.
3. Real options models
First, we present a very simple stylized model within a cost-benefit framework to analyze investment in health technology. Then we present its application to the medical decision-making and finally to the public health decision-making.
3.1 Real options model applied to investment
Following Palmer and Smith (2000), we present a very simple stylized model within a cost-benefit framework in order to highlight some ideas underlying the real options model, i.e. irreversibility and the ability to invest in the future. We begin with a simple example in which investment decisions are made at two discrete moments at time. Consider an investment opportunity in a new healthcare technology that costs an initial amount (
We assume the benefits of the technology (B) to evolve over time according to the geometric Brownian motion, such as:
The value of the technology is expressed in terms of net benefits, i.e. the value of benefits at time t
Under uncertainty, the decision to adopt a particular technology is based on expected present discounted value (PDV) of the net benefit, so that when comparing mutually exclusive strategies, the optimal strategy is simply the one with the highest expected PDV.
Uncertainty increases the expected Net Benefits (NB) associated with the technology.
Proof: See Online Appendix A.
The expected NB is positively proportional to
3.1.1 Option value of the investment
The decision as to whether or not to invest in a new technology constitutes an optimal stopping problem for which the relevant Bellman equation is:
Investment in the new technology occurs only if the benefits exceed the costs.
Proof: See Online Appendix A.
From the comparative statics shown in Online Appendix A, if the uncertainty (
The model presented gives clear indications regarding investment decisions under uncertainty. It predicts that the higher the volatility of the benefits, the more valuable the option to invest will be and so the fewer investments will be observed. Conversely, the higher the trend of the benefits and the higher the discount factor, the less valuable the option to invest will be and so the more investments one would expect to observe.
3.1.2 The timing and probability of investment
It would be interesting to ascertain, from any point within the continuation region, the likelihood that investment will become optimal in the future. It is important for the decision-maker to know the expected time that will transpire until the decision of investing becomes optimal.
Using standard properties of the Brownian motion and the lognormal distribution (see Dixit (1993)), closed-form solutions for the probability
Investment will become optimal with certainty provided that
For the set of parameters for which
The real options model presented above evaluates the optimal timing and probability for making an investment in health technology, considering uncertainty and irreversibility. The results of the model reveal that optimal investment should take longer the higher the uncertainty regarding the future benefits of the new technology. By waiting, one avoids the risk of investing heavily in a technology that might not yield the expected benefits. If there is a positive trend in the technology’s benefits (i.e. the benefits are increasing over time), the model suggests that it is better to invest sooner. This is because capturing these benefits early can provide significant value, especially if they are growing rapidly. A higher discount rate implies that future benefits are worth much less in today’s terms. Thus, if the discount rate is high, it is better to invest sooner to realize the benefits before they are heavily discounted. Delaying investment would mean that even if the technology’s benefits are realized in the future, their present value (due to the high discount rate) would be much diminished.
3.2 Real options model applied to medical decision
We follow de Mello-Sampayo (2014) to illustrate the role that uncertainty and irreversibility can play in determining the decision regarding whether to move a patient to the next treatment in a sequence. First, a sector model is set up that allows health capital to be augmented through public investment. Here, it is assumed there are two lines of treatment in treating a chronic disease, denoted by
Assume a one-sector model that allows health capital to be augmented through public investment. An individual’s health status is determined by public health measures such as provision of clinical facilities, sanitation, inoculation, and disease control programs (see Chakraborty (2004)). Population individuals are endowed with one unit of labor which is inelastically supplied to firms and receive wage income at the rate
Decision-makers observe and decide the viability, utility, and characteristics of healthcare goods and services only after using those products or services. Thus, the quality of a healthcare good or service can be ascertained only upon its consumption. In such cases, a drop in price is often interpreted by the prospective consumer as a drop in quality or utility of the product or service. Indeed, it is possible for the demand curve for medical care to be upward sloping [3], even though medical care is a non-inferior good, a relationship that has some empirical support (Hoi and Robson, 1981; Hau, 2008; Dusansky and Cagatay, 2010). Under this condition the demand for medical care is given by:
The benefit increases with the number of healthcare goods or services demanded (
The cost of the technology,
Treatment switch occurs only if the relative benefit associated with
Proof: See Online Appendix B.
It follows from Equation (3.2.6) and the assumptions on the parameters that the value of
Following the comparative statics shown in Online Appendix B, the model presented gives clear indications regarding treatment switch (TS) decisions under cost uncertainty. It predicts that the higher the volatility (
Figures 1 and 2 illustrate, respectively, the impact of
Figure 1 illustrates the probability that
In Figure 2, our simulation benchmark values are expressed in year terms so that the simulations for the expected time for optimal treatment switch can be read in years. Figure 2 shows that the lower is
Viewed from the perspective of real options theory, the model presented above sheds new light on some debates about switching treatments. de Mello-Sampayo (2014)’s theoretical model suggests that cost uncertainty discourages switching treatments. The stochastic model also illustrates that as technologies become less cost competitive, the cost uncertainty becomes more dominant. With limited substitutability, higher quality of technologies will increase the demand for those technologies disregarding the cost uncertainty. Several key insights emerge. Irreversibility raises the value of the option-preserving treatment. The existence of an option value means that a seemingly poorer treatment may be the better choice when considering lifetime welfare. Optimal decision-making requires a careful comparison of the “costs” of a less effective treatment for a condition today with the “benefits” of more effective treatments in the future.
3.3 Real options model applied to public health
In this section we develop an epidemiological-based real options model based on de Mello-Sampayo (2024) to illustrate the role that uncertainty can play in determining the decision regarding when to exit the lockdown without provoking a resurgence of the disease.
3.3.1 Epidemiological model
A simple epidemiological model for a COVID-19 pandemic for which there is a considerable post-infection incubation period in which the exposed person is not yet contagious, is the Susceptible-Exposed-Infected-Removed (SEIR) model (Hethcote, 2000; Li and Muldowney, 1995; Avery et al., 2020a, b; Blackwood and Childs, 2018). Ignoring births and deaths from non-COVID-19 causes, the population at the start of the epidemic is normalized to 1, and at each time t, the population is compartmentalized based on their infection status: susceptible (S) to infection; exposed (E), i.e. likely to be infected when exposed to the virus, but not yet contagious; infected (I) and contagious; and removed (R), who have recovered or died from the disease. The interaction between the susceptible and infected is permitted through the productive contact
Initially, under certain common assumptions (Jones, 2007), i.e. individuals who are infected remain infectious until they recover or die, infected individuals who recover acquire complete immunity, and ignoring uncertainty, the SEIR model translates into a system of four differential equations to relate the rates at which the population moves from one stage to another, and in which the time unit is one day:
At the optimum, the government uses social distancing or mitigation measures to stop the infected population from increasing, i.e.
3.3.2 Uncertainty in the spread of the disease
There is uncertainty in the future levels of infection due to environmental and demographic noise associated with the transmission process for infection. The decision-maker is faced with the following choice: should mitigation measures be stopped immediately, or should the decision-maker wait to learn more about the progression of the epidemic? Waiting allows the decision-maker to determine whether the level of infection worsens or improves over time.
To include uncertainty into the decision-making, we assume that the level of exposed, E, can be described by a stochastic process. Traditionally, the geometric Brownian motion, which assumes that the mean level of infection grows exponentially, has been used to characterize stochastic processes (Dangerfield et al., 2018). While such an assumption is a good approximation in the early stages of the epidemic, it does not capture the slowing in the rate of infection as the level of infection becomes large due to the limited number of susceptible individuals. Thus, we assume the exposed population follows a Driftless stochastic process, i.e. our best guess of the exposed population for tomorrow is what we have at the present.
Suppose that the government applies the lockdown (L) as the social distancing measure (
The exposed population under lockdown becomes an average of both exposed at home and using masks weighted by the share of population assigned to each group:
Now, assume that the government is searching for a way to exit the lockdown without provoking a resurgence of the disease. For that we analyze the timing and probability of exiting the lockdown under uncertainty.
The government will end the lockdown when the expected Exposed population staying at home is higher than that attained when just using masks.
Proof: See Online Appendix C.
The decision-maker will choose to relax the measures only if the Exposed population associated with staying at home exceeds that of a situation of only using masks, i.e.
Exit Lockdown
Thus, the model presented gives clear indications regarding the exit of lockdown decision under uncertainty. It predicts that the higher the uncertainty (
These results are confirmed using simulations. The simulations are performed using Portuguese data on COVID-19 between 2020 and 2021 from various sources. Table C1 in Online Appendix C presents the range and the base value of each parameter.
Figures 3 and 4 illustrate the impact of
Figure 3 illustrates the impact of
Figure 4 simulates the effect of changes in
In summary, the lower the uncertainty affecting the exposed population subject to lockdown, the more likely policy change is to become optimal and the sooner it is expected to occur. Moreover, exiting lockdown becomes likelier and is expected sooner, the closer the two processes are, i.e.
This model extends the literature by applying the real options theory, a framework for decision-making under uncertainty, to an epidemiological model of disease spread. By incorporating uncertainty into the analysis, the study aims to determine the optimal timing for exiting lockdown. The real options approach allows for the evaluation of the economic value of deferring the decision to exit lockdown until more information becomes available.
4. Discussion
This paper presented a mapping of the studies published to date applying the real options theory to various areas of healthcare. Real options theory relates to decision-making under uncertainty and specifically to the value of deferring uncertain unrecoverable decisions to a later time. In the evaluation of healthcare technologies and programs, this dimension of value originates from the possibility of delaying a decision if there is an expectation that better information will become available in the future. The seminal paper of Palmer and Smith (2000) argues that, in the presence of uncertain, irreversible decisions, the possibility of deferring the decision until some later time, when better information regarding costs and benefits may become available, has an economic value that is not accounted for in traditional economic evaluations based on net expected values.
The real options approach has been widely employed in the healthcare sector with a focus on optimizing outcomes. It finds application in diverse areas, investment analysis (Smyth and Swinand, 2002; Williams et al., 2007; Levaggi et al., 2009; Levaggi and Michele, 2004; Pertile, 2008, 2009; Pertile et al., 2009), technology assessment (Eckermann and Willan, 2008; van Loon et al., 2012; Thijssen and Bregantini, 2017; Oliveira and Zambujal-Oliveira, 2018; Tolga, 2020; Chalkidou et al., 2008), decision-making in public health (Favato et al., 2012; Pertile et al., 2014; Park, 2016; Attema et al., 2010; Megiddo et al., 2019), and medical decision-making (Driffield and Smith, 2007; Grutters et al., 2011; Meyer and Rees, 2012; Forster and Pertile, 2013b; de Mello-Sampayo, 2014, 2015; Shechter et al., 2008; Zivin and Neideill, 2009). These earlier studies applying real options theory to decision-making in the healthcare sector often use the option to defer (Fornaro et al., 2021). This option is commonly employed in investment analyses to decide whether to adopt new technologies for treatments, as well as in cases involving the postponement of vaccination or in cases to decide whether, when, and if a treatment should occur, i.e. watchful waiting. Investment analyses in the healthcare sector follow a similar logic to that applied in other sectors, wherein the investor seeks to maximize the expected present value of the payoff. Similarly, in healthcare scenarios such as watchful waiting, the same logic applies due to the presence of irreversibility and risk. For instance, the decision to initiate treatment is irreversible, as the resources allocated cannot be utilized for any other purpose. However, the option to defer treatment remains reversible. For example, Grutters et al. (2011) examine the adoption of proton therapy compared to body stereotactic radiotherapy in the treatment of inoperable stage I non-small cell lung cancer, highlighting the relevance of information in selecting the best treatment at a specific time. The value of information is crucial, particularly due to the technical uncertainty involved in certain treatments, which may lead decision-makers to choose treatment options that are not necessarily the most effective. More information mitigates risks and enhances expected returns.
In this study, we began by introducing a straightforward stylized model that applies option pricing principles to assess investments in new technologies, within a cost-benefit framework (Palmer and Smith, 2000). The aim was to highlight the main ideas underlying the real options model, i.e. uncertainty, irreversibility, and the ability to invest subsequently. This type of model has been applied to analyzing investments in diverse areas such as machines, technologies, pharmaceuticals stocks, health insurance plans, public health initiatives, new treatments, infrastructure, and health systems. Those studies represent traditional applications of real options, wherein investors analyze whether investing their capital in a particular project yields returns higher than the company’s cost of capital. The options to expand and abandon are particularly relevant when evaluating technology investments. For instance, (Levaggi et al., 2009) illustrate how real options can be used to expand investments strategically, thereby optimizing returns while minimizing the associated risks. In another vein, (Pertile et al., 2014) discuss how the real options approach can be used to evaluate the option to abandon a project when conditions are unfavorable or when better opportunities arise.
To illustrate a real options model applied to medical decision-making, we used a stochastic dynamic model of sequential therapeutic regimes that underscores the importance of characterizing uncertainty (de Mello-Sampayo, 2014). Cost fluctuations, among other factors, render the outcome of any treatment switch uncertain, so that decision-makers might have to wait for more information before optimally switching treatments, especially when the incremental cost per Quality-Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) gained cannot be fully recovered later on. Since in most cases decision-makers are not compelled to switch treatments at any specific moment, they hold an option to switch treatments that should only be exercised when it is optimal to do so. The intuition for these results is deepened when we recognize that one of the principal features driving our results is that patients have particular characteristics that make technology’s cost uncertain. Thus, under irreversibility, low-risk patients must begin the option-preserving treatment as soon as possible, which is precisely when the second-line treatment is least valuable. As the costs of reversing current treatment impacts fall, it becomes more feasible to provide the option-preserving treatment to these low-risk individuals later on. The study builds upon previous studies such as Driffield and Smith (2007) and Meyer and Rees (2012), acknowledging the unique nature of medical decision-making. These studies address the issue of time-related decisions made by risk-averse individuals and examine how an increase in uncertainty regarding a patient’s health state often makes waiting more attractive. Unlike traditional investment portfolios, medical treatments cannot be diversified simultaneously, i.e. there is an inherent limitation in medical treatment strategies that prevent applying multiple different treatments at the same time for a single patient or condition, in contrast to financial investment strategies. In this context, the option to switch treatments becomes critical as discussed by de Mello-Sampayo (2015). Since treatments cannot be diversified simultaneously, decision-makers (like doctors or patients) hold the option to switch from one treatment to another at the most opportune time, based on evolving information about the patient’s condition and the effectiveness of the current treatment.
To exemplify how a real options model can be applied to public health decision-making, we derived an options model from a Susceptible-Exposed-Infectious-Recovered (SEIR) framework to analyze the probability and optimal timing of lockdown exit (de Mello-Sampayo, 2024). This analysis was conducted in the context of an ongoing pandemic in which the decision to exit lockdown is uncertain because it depends on the progression of the virus and the effectiveness of control measures. The theoretical model argues that in the presence of uncertainty the possibility of deferring the decision until some later time when better information may become available has an economic value. This concept is especially relevant to the context of the COVID-19 pandemic, in which crucial decisions regarding lockdown measures affect public health, the economy, and societal well-being. In the fight against the pandemic the value of deferring the decision to exit lockdown is underscored by the availability of information related to the disease’s transmission dynamics. Key factors contributing to a reduction in uncertainty include a better understanding of how the virus spreads, the dissemination of clear and evidence-based public health guidance, and the development and distribution of vaccines. Information about how the disease spreads, clear public health guidance, and vaccines, decreases the uncertainty regarding exposure and transmission of COVID-19. This study aligns with the findings of related research (Chalkiadakis et al., 2021; Varghese et al., 2021; Abrams and Greenhawt, 2020), which emphasize the role of information and knowledge in reducing uncertainty related to the exposure and transmission of COVID-19. By leveraging a real options model within a SEIR framework, our research contributes to the scientific understanding of how decision-makers can navigate the complex landscape of public health decisions during a pandemic characterized by high levels of uncertainty.
Growth in the availability of treatments for chronic diseases that require permanent intervention, along with general increases in life expectancy, suggests that the impact of omitting option values from evaluations will only become greater. While it is difficult to systematically assess the magnitude of the bias induced from ignoring option values, the only empirical study in the health domain reported an increase in consumer willingness-to-pay of approximately 53% when option values were considered (Smith, 2007). Extending one’s life through medical technology provides patients with the option to potentially benefit from future advances in healthcare (Lakdawalla et al., 2018). This real options value emerges when a health technology not only prolongs life but also opens up opportunities for patients to access forthcoming innovations in medicine (Cook et al., 2011). The importance of considering real options when discussing value in healthcare has recently been highlighted (Lakdawalla et al., 2018; Krüger and Svensson, 2009; Garrison et al., 2017; Smith and Yip, 2016). While the economic literature has previously identified real options value as an additional component of value for specific medical products (Smith, 2007; Eckermann and Willan, 2008), it is typically not accounted for in the conventional projections of QALYs gained. These QALYs typically consider expected survival and health-related utility over a patient’s remaining lifetime. Investing in life-extending medical technology can be seen as buying an option to benefit from future advances in healthcare. Other things being equal, a technology that extends life in an area with promising innovations holds greater value (Li et al., 2022).
Implementing real options theory in healthcare decision-making faces several limitations. Firstly, the intrinsic uncertainty and complexity of healthcare outcomes challenge the accurate assessment of option values. Unlike financial markets, where assets have readily quantifiable values, the outcomes in healthcare, such as patient health or disease progression, are not easily quantified. Secondly, the dynamic and often unpredictable nature of healthcare policy and regulation can invalidate the assumptions underpinning real options analysis, rendering the conclusions less reliable. Lastly, there’s a moral and ethical dimension in healthcare decision-making that is not typically present in financial decision-making. Balancing financial considerations with ethical obligations to patients adds a layer of complexity that real options theory may not adequately address. These limitations suggest that while real options theory can provide valuable insights, it must be applied with caution and in conjunction with other decision-making frameworks in the healthcare sector.
While real options theory offers a valuable approach for decisions under uncertainty and where the timing of decisions is crucial, other models like Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA), decision trees, Markov models, and Bayesian decision models have their respective strengths in different scenarios. The choice of model depends on the specific decision context, the nature of the healthcare problem, the availability of data, and the need for dynamic versus static analysis. For instances, CEA provides a static comparison based on current data but may not fully capture the value of deferred decisions or evolving scenarios and decision tree analysis presents an intuitive way to visualize decision paths, integrating probabilities and potential outcomes. This method is most effective when dealing with a limited set of discrete outcomes (Vassolo et al., 2021). Bayesian Decision Models dynamically update probabilities with new information, suitable for evolving healthcare scenarios, yet they require extensive initial data and are computationally intensive (Luce et al., 2001).
5. Conclusion
Our study shows the versatility of the real options model, demonstrating its applicability in diverse fields in healthcare, where it aids decision-makers in assessing investment opportunities, medical decisions, and public health decisions, among others. By considering strategic decision-making and the value of flexibility, real options theory enhances the evaluation of healthcare investments, policy analysis, patient outcomes, and resource allocation. These applications contribute to a more comprehensive understanding of decision-making under uncertainty in the field of health economics, leading to improved decision-making and outcomes in the ever-evolving healthcare industry.
Figures
Notes
Stochastic process, also known as a random process, accounts for certain levels of unpredictability or randomness.
Wiener process is a stochastic process. The initial value of all Wiener processes is 0; past values of these processes do not influence any future changes in their value (this is what makes the processes stochastic).
In this model set-up, the mechanism that leads health to be a Giffen good also involves a wealth consideration. When the price of treatment falls, the patient is effectively wealthier, he can afford more treatments generally, and so he needs fewer treatments of this kind. Housing is another example of a non-inferior good whose own-demand can be upward sloping (see Dusansky and Koç (Dusansky and Koç (2007)).
Martingale process: the fluctuations in exposed population are a sequence of random variables for which, at a particular time, the conditional expectation of the next value in the sequence is equal to the present value, regardless of all prior values.
Online Appendix
The supplementary material for this article can be found online.
References
Abrams, E. and Greenhawt, M. (2020), “Risk communication during COVID-19”, Journal of Allergy and Clinical Immunology: In Practice, Vol. 8 No. 6, pp. 1791-1794, doi: 10.1016/j.jaip.2020.04.012.
Attema, A., Lugnér, A. and Feenstra, T. (2010), “Investment in antiviral drugs: a real options approach”, Health Economics, Vol. 19 No. 10, pp. 1240-1254, doi: 10.1002/hec.1549.
Avery, C., Bossert, W., Clark, A., Ellison, G. and Ellison, S. (2020a), “An economist's guide to epidemiology models of infectious disease”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 79-104, doi: 10.1257/jep.34.4.79.
Avery, C., Bossert, W., Clark, A., Ellison, G. and Ellison, S. (2020b), “Policy implications of models of the spread of coronavirus: perspectives and opportunities for economists”, NBER Working Papers 27007.
Blackwood, J. and Childs, L. (2018), “An introduction to compartmental modeling for the budding infectious disease modeler”, Letters in Biomathematics, Vol. 5 No. 1, pp. 195-221, doi: 10.1080/23737867.2018.1509026.
Chakraborty, S. (2004), “Endogenous lifetime and economic growth”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 116 No. 1, pp. 119-137, doi: 10.1016/j.jet.2003.07.005.
Chalkiadakis, I., Yan, H., Peters, G. and Shevchenko, P. (2021), “Infection rate models for COVID-19: model risk and public health news sentiment exposure adjustments”, PLOS ONE, Vol. 16 No. 6, p. e0253381, doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0253381.
Chalkidou, L., Lord, J., Fischer, A. and Littlejohns, P. (2008), “Evidence-based decision making: when should we wait for more information?”, Health Affairs, Vol. 27 No. 6, pp. 1642-1653, doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.27.6.1642.
Claxton, K. (1999), “The irrelevance of inference: a decision making approach to the stochastic evaluation of health care technologies”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 341-364, doi: 10.1016/s0167-6296(98)00039-3.
Cook, J., Golec, J., Vernon, J. and Pink, G. (2011), “Real option value and path dependence in oncology innovation”, International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 225-238, doi: 10.1080/13571516.2011.584428.
Dangerfield, C., Whalley, A., Hanley, N. and Gilligan, C.A. (2018), “What a difference a stochastic process makes: epidemiological-based real options models of optimal treatment of disease”, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 70 No. 3, pp. 691-711, doi: 10.1007/s10640-017-0168-x.
de Mello-Sampayo, F. (2014), “The timing and probability of treatment switch under cost uncertainty: an application to patients with gastrointestinal stromal tumor”, Value in Health, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 215-222, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2013.12.008.
de Mello-Sampayo, F. (2015), “HIV patients' decision of switching to second-line antiretroviral therapy in India”, AIDS Care, Vol. 27 No. 7, pp. 900-906, doi: 10.1080/09540121.2015.1015480.
de Mello-Sampayo, F. (2022), “On the timing and probability of presurgical teledermatology: how it becomes the dominant strategy”, Health Care Management Science, Vol. 2022 No. 25, pp. 389-405, doi: 10.1007/s10729-021-09574-0.
de Mello-Sampayo, F. (2024), “Uncertainty in healthcare policy decisions: an epidemiological real options approach to COVID-19 lockdown exits”, Health Economics Discussion Group (HEDG) Working Papers 24/01, York.
Dixit, A. (1993), “The art of smooth pasting”, in Jacques, L. and Hugo, S. (Eds), Vol. 55 of series Fundamentals of Pure and Applied Economics, Harwood Academic Publishers, Reading.
Dixit, A. and Pindyck, R. (1994), Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Driffield, T. and Smith, P. (2007), “A real options approach to watchful waiting: theory and an illustration”, Medical Decision Making, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 178-188, doi: 10.1177/0272989x06297390.
Dusansky, R. and Cagatay, K. (2010), “Implications of the interaction between insurance choice and medical care demand”, Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol. 77 No. 1, pp. 129-144, doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2009.01335.x.
Dusansky, R. and Koç, C. (2007), “The capital gains effect in the demand for housing”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 61 No. 2, pp. 287-298, doi: 10.1016/j.jue.2006.07.008.
Eckermann, S. and Willan, A. (2008), “The option value of delay in health technology assessment”, Medical Decision Making, Vol. 28 No. 3, pp. 300-305, doi: 10.1177/0272989x07312477.
Favato, G., Baio, G., Capone, A., Marcellusi, A. and Saverio Mennini, F. (2012), “A novel method to value real options in health care: the case of a multicohort human papillomavirus vaccination strategy”, Clinical Therapeutics, Vol. 35 No. 7, pp. 904-914, doi: 10.1016/j.clinthera.2013.05.003.
Fornaro, G., Federici, C., Rognoni, C. and Ciani, O. (2021), “Broadening the concept of value: a scoping review on the option value of medical technologies”, Value in Health, Vol. 24 No. 7, pp. 1045-1058, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2020.12.018.
Forster, M. and Pertile, P. (2013a), “Optimal decision rules for HTA under uncertainty: a wider, dynamic perspective”, Health Economics, Vol. 22 No. 12, pp. 1507-1514, doi: 10.1002/hec.2893.
Forster, M. and Pertile, P. (2013b), “Optimal decision rules for HTA under uncertainty: a wider, dynamic perspective”, Health Econ, Vol. 22 No. 12, pp. 1507-1514, doi: 10.1002/hec.2893.
Garrison, L. Jr, Kamal-Bahl, S. and Towse, A. (2017), “Toward a broader concept of value: identifying and defining elements for an expanded cost-effectiveness analysis”, Value in Health, Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 213-216, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2016.12.005.
Grutters, J., Abrams, K., de Ruysscher, D., Pijls-Johannesma, M., Peters, H.J., Beutner, E., Lambin, P. and Joore, M.A. (2011), “When to wait for more evidence? Real options analysis in proton therapy”, Oncologist, Vol. 16 No. 12, pp. 1752-1761, doi: 10.1634/theoncologist.2011-0029.
Hau, A. (2008), “When is a coinsurance-type insurance policy inferior or even Giffen?”, Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol. 75 No. 2, pp. 343-364, doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2008.00263.x.
Hethcote, H. (2000), “The mathematics of infectious diseases”, SIAM Review, Vol. 42 No. 4, pp. 599-653, doi: 10.1137/s0036144500371907.
Hoi, M. and Robson, A. (1981), “Insurance as a giffen good”, Economics Letters, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 47-51, doi: 10.1016/0165-1765(81)90091-4.
Jones, J. (2007), Notes on R0, Department of Anthropological Sciences, Califonia.
Krüger, N. and Svensson, M. (2009), “The impact of real options on willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions”, J Health Econ, Vol. 28 No. 3, pp. 563-569, doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2009.01.002.
Lakdawalla, D., Doshi, J., Garrison, L., Phelps, C.E., Basu, A. and Danzon, P.M. (2018), “Defining elements of value in health care—a health economics approach: an ISPOR Special Task Force report [3]”, Value in Health, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 131-139, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2017.12.007.
Levaggi, R. and Michele, M. (2004), “Investment in hospital care technology under different purchasing rules: a real option approach”, Bulletin of Economic Research, Vol. 60 No. 2, pp. 159-181, doi: 10.1111/j.0307-3378.2008.00274.x.
Levaggi, R., Moretto, M. and Rebba, V. (2009), “Investment decisions in hospital technology when physicians are devoted workers”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, Vol. 18 No. 5, pp. 487-512, doi: 10.1080/10438590802547209.
Li, M. and Muldowney, J. (1995), “Global stability for the SEIR model in epidemiology”, Mathematical Biosciences, Vol. 125 No. 2, pp. 155-164, doi: 10.1016/0025-5564(95)92756-5.
Li, M., Garrison, L.J., Lee, W., Kowal, S., Wong, W. and Veenstra, D. (2022), “Pragmatic guide to assessing real option value for medical technologies”, Value in Health, Vol. 25 No. 11, pp. 1878-1884, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2022.05.014.
Luce, B., Shih, Y. and Claxton, K. (2001), “Bayesian approaches to technology assessment and decision making”, International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 1-5, doi: 10.1017/s0266462301104010.
Megiddo, I., Drabik, D., Bedford, T., Morton, A., Wesseler, J. and Laxminarayan, R. (2019), “Investing in antibiotics to alleviate future catastrophic outcomes: what is the value of having an effective antibiotic to mitigate pandemic influenza?”, Health Economics, Vol. 28 No. 4, pp. 556-571, doi: 10.1002/hec.3867.
Meyer, E. and Rees, R. (2012), “Watchfully waiting: medical intervention as an optimal investment decision”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 31 No. 2, pp. 349-358, doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2012.02.002.
Oliveira, A. and Zambujal-Oliveira, J. (2018), “Healthcare technology assessment under uncertainty: the case of the digital medical linear accelerators”, Operations Research for Health Care, Vol. 16, pp. 1-9, doi: 10.1016/j.orhc.2017.10.004.
Palmer, S. and Smith, P. (2000), “Incorporating option values into the economic evaluation of health care technologies”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 19 No. 5, pp. 755-766, doi: 10.1016/s0167-6296(00)00048-5.
Park, H. (2016), “A real option analysis for stochastic disease control and vaccine stockpile policy: an application to H1N1 in Korea”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 53, pp. 187-194, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2015.12.005.
Pertile, P. (2008), “Investment in health technologies in a competitive model with real options”, Journal of Public Economic Theory, Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 923-952, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2008.00392.x.
Pertile, P. (2009), “An extension of the real option approach to the evaluation of health care technologies: the case of positron emission tomography”, International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 317-332, doi: 10.1007/s10754-008-9053-z.
Pertile, P., Torri, E., Flor, L. and Tardivo, S. (2009), “The timing of adoption of positron emission tomography: a real options approach”, Health Care Management Science, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 217-227, doi: 10.1007/s10729-008-9085-4.
Pertile, P., Forster, M. and La Torre, D. (2014), “Optimal Bayesian sequential sampling rules for the economic evaluation of health technologies”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (Statistics in Society), Vol. 177 No. 2, pp. 419-438, doi: 10.1111/rssa.12025.
Sculpher, M. and Claxton, K. (2005), “Establishing the cost effectiveness of new pharmaceuticals under conditions of uncertainty – when is there sufficient evidence?”, Value in Health, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 433-446, doi: 10.1111/j.1524-4733.2005.00033.x.
Sengupta, B. and Kreier, R. (2011), “A dynamic model of health plan choice from a real options perspective”, Atlantic Economic Journal, Vol. 39 No. 4, pp. 401-419, doi: 10.1007/s11293-011-9287-x.
Shechter, S., Bailey, M., Schaefer, A.J. and Roberts, M.S. (2008), “The optimal time to initiate HIV therapy under ordered health states”, Operational Research, Vol. 56 No. 1, pp. 20-33, doi: 10.1287/opre.1070.0480.
Smith, R. (2007), “Use, option and externality values: are contingent valuation studies in health care mis-specified?”, Health Economics, Vol. 16 No. 8, pp. 861-869, doi: 10.1002/hec.1189.
Smith, P. and Yip, W. (2016), “The economics of health system design”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 21-40, doi: 10.1093/oxrep/grv018.
Smyth, J. and Swinand, P. (2002), “Evaluating capital investment opportunities: capturing the value of flexibility: real-option analysis helps managers value assets and flexibility in an uncertain environment”, Healthcare Financial Management, Vol. 56 No. 11, pp. 60-65.
Thijssen, J. and Bregantini, D. (2017), “Costly sequential experimentation and project valuation with an application to health technology assessment”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 77, pp. 202-229, doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2017.01.016.
Tolga, A. (2020), “Real options valuation of an IoT based healthcare device with interval type-2 fuzzy numbers”, Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, Vol. 69, 100693, doi: 10.1016/j.seps.2019.02.008.
van Loon, J., Grutters, J. and Macbeth, F. (2012), “Evaluation of novel radiotherapy technologies: what evidence is needed to assess their clinical and cost effectiveness, and how should we get it?”, Lancet Oncology, Vol. 13 No. 4, pp. e169-e177, doi: 10.1016/s1470-2045(11)70379-5.
Varghese, N., Sabat, I., Neumann-Böhme, S., Schreyögg, J., Stargardt, T., Torbica, A., van Exel, J., Barros, P.P. and Brouwer, W. (2021), “Risk communication during COVID-19: a descriptive study on familiarity with, adherence to and trust in the WHO preventive measures”, PLoS ONE, Vol. 16 No. 4, p. e0250872, doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0250872.
Vassolo, R., Mac Cawley, A., Tortorella, G., Fogliatto, F.S., Tlapa, D. and Narayanamurthy, G. (2021), “Hospital investment decisions in healthcare 4.0 technologies: scoping review and framework for exploring challenges, trends, and research directions”, Journal of Medical Internet Research, Vol. 23 No. 8, e27571, doi: 10.2196/27571.
Williams, D., Hammes, P. and Karahalis, G. (2007), “Real options reasoning in healthcare: an integrative approach and synopsis”, Journal of Healthcare Management, Vol. 52 No. 3, pp. 170-186, doi: 10.1097/00115514-200705000-00007.
Zivin, J.G. and Neideill, M. (2009), “Medical technology adoption, uncertainty, and irreversibilities: is a bird in the hand really worth more than two in the bush?”, Health Economics, Vol. 19 No. 2, pp. 142-153, doi: 10.1002/hec.1455.
Further reading
Aitchison, J. and Brown, J. (1957), The Lognormal Distribution, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2020), “Supplemental data measuring the effects of the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic on the labor market”, [Online], available at: https://www.bls.gov/cps/effects-of-the-coronavirus-covid-19-pandemic.htm
Chae, S., Lee, L., Lee, H.M., Jung, N., Le, Q.A., Mafwele, B.J., Lee, T.H., Kim, D.H. and Lee, J.W. (2020), “Estimation of infection rate and predictions of disease spreading based on initial individuals infected with COVID-19”, Frontiers in Physics, Vol. 8 No. 311, doi: 10.3389/fphy.2020.00311.
Ferguson, N., Laydon, D., Nedjati-Gilani, G., Imai, N., Ainslie, K., Baguelin, M., Bhatia, S., Boonyasiri, A., Cucunuba Perez, Z., Cuomo-Dannenburg, G., Dighe, A., Dorigatti, I., Fu, H., Gaythorpe, K., Green, W., Hamlet, A., Hinsley, W., Okell, L., Van Elsland, S., Thompson, H., Verity, R., Volz, E., Wang, H., Wang, Y., Walker, P., Walters, C., Winskill, P., Whittaker, C., Donnelly, C., Riley, S. and Ghani, A. (2020), Report 9: Impact of Non-pharmaceutical Interventions (NPIs) to Reduce COVID-19 Mortality and Healthcare Demand, Imperial College COVID-19 Response Team, London.
Hislop, J., Quayyum, Z., Elders, A., Fraser, C., Jenkinson, D., Mowatt, G., Sharma, P., Vale, L. and Petty, R. (2011), “Clinical effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of imatinib dose escalation for the treatment of unresectable and/or metastatic gastrointestinal stromal tumours that have progressed on treatment at a dose of 400 mg/day”, Health Technology Assessment, Vol. 15 No. 25, pp. 1-178, doi: 10.3310/hta15250.
Lauer, S., Grantz, K., Bi, Q., Jones, F., Zheng, Q., Meredith, H.R., Azman, A.S., Reich, N.G. and Lessler, J. (2020), “The incubation period of coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) from publicly reported confirmed cases: estimation and application”, Annals of Internal Medicine, Vol. 172 No. 9, pp. 577-582, doi: 10.7326/m20-0504.
Øksendal, B. (2003), Stochastic Differential Equations: an Introduction with Applications, Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg/New York.
O'Mahony, J.F. and Paulden, M. (2014), “NICE's selective application of differential discounting: ambiguous, inconsistent, and unjustified”, Value in Health, Vol. 17 No. 5, pp. 493-496, doi: 10.1016/j.jval.2013.02.014.
Spinner, C., Gottlieb, R., Criner, G., Arribas López, J.R., Cattelan, A.M., Soriano Viladomiu, A., Ogbuagu, O., Malhotra, P., Mullane, K.M., Castagna, A., Chai, L.Y.A., Roestenberg, M., Tsang, O.T.Y., Bernasconi, E., Le Turnier, P., Chang, S.C., SenGupta, D., Hyland, R.H., Osinusi, A.O., Cao, H., Blair, C., Wang, H., Gaggar, A., Brainard, D.M., McPhail, M.J., Bhagani, S., Ahn, M.Y., Sanyal, A.J., Huhn, G. and Marty, F.M. (2020), “Effect of remdesivir vs standard care on clinical status at 11 days in patients with moderate COVID-19: a randomized clinical trial”, JAMA, Vol. 324 No. 11, pp. 1048-1057, doi: 10.1001/jama.2020.16349.
Teles, P. (2020), “A time-dependent SEIR model to analyse the evolution of the SARS-covid-2 epidemic outbreak in Portugal”, arXiv: Populations and Evolution, available at: https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:215737174
Thijssen, J. (2013), An Easy-To-Use Toolkit for Solving Optimal Stopping Problems, Department of Economics, University of York, York, Vols. 13/24.
Wilson, J., Connock, M., Song, F., Yao, G., Fry-Smith, A., Raftery, J. and Peake, D. (2005), “Imatinib mesylate for the treatment of patients with unresectable and/or metastatic gastrointestinal stromal tumours: systematic review and economic evaluation”, Health Technology Assessment, Vol. 9 No. 25, pp. 1-142, doi: 10.3310/hta9250.
Acknowledgements
Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia, underUIDB/00315/2020 grant is gratefully acknowledged. The funding body had no influence in the design of the study, collection, analysis, or interpretation of data, or in writing the manuscript.