Relevance of middle-income trap (MIT) to the vision-based development in Bangladesh

M. Aminul Islam Akanda (Department of Economics, Comilla University, Comilla, Bangladesh)

Journal of Business and Socio-economic Development

ISSN: 2635-1374

Article publication date: 17 November 2022

Issue publication date: 26 May 2023

691

Abstract

Purpose

This study aims to investigate whether Bangladesh would avoid the middle-income trap (MIT) in its transition to a high-income country (HIC) according to its “Vision 2041”.

Design/methodology/approach

Using both actual and forecasted secondary data, three MIT models of different approaches were used to evaluate the government’s vision-based projections. Moreover, crucial indicators of deindustrialization and institutional strength were linked to the investigation of potential transitions.

Findings

According to the absolute definition and international forecasts, the Bangladesh economy might not fall into an MIT at its lower-middle-income level within the intended period due to being shorter than the defined limit. However, its real GDP per capita relative to the USA would remain far below the defined threshold limit of an upper-middle-income country (UMC) in 2041. Meanwhile, Bangladesh has reached the third of the five gradual phases and is awaiting a new transition in 2029. However, its vision-based plan would face challenges such as skills gaps, institutional reforms and successive global crises.

Practical implications

Bangladesh might be trapped in MIT at the UMC level in the 2030s, with no path to renovate after the demographic dividend ends in 2047. In this regard, the government must demonstrate a strong political will to ensure the effectiveness of its policies and the viability of its institutions.

Originality/value

This study not only compared projections to forecasts using different MIT models but also connected transition phases to industrial policies and institutional strengths.

Keywords

Citation

Akanda, M.A.I. (2023), "Relevance of middle-income trap (MIT) to the vision-based development in Bangladesh", Journal of Business and Socio-economic Development, Vol. 3 No. 3, pp. 279-292. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBSED-08-2022-0091

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2022, M. Aminul Islam Akanda

License

Published in Journal of Business and Socio-economic Development. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

LIC, LMC, UMC and HIC stand for the World Bank’s classification of low, lower-middle, upper-middle and high-income countries, respectively. Developed countries used to follow gradual transitions from the LICs to the LMCs, UMCs and HICs. Out of the 101 LMCs and UMCs in 1960, only 13 countries progressed to the HICs by 2008 (World Bank, 2013). Such failure in timely transition was first coined as the “middle-income trap (MIT)” in 2007. The authors, in their original articles, provided a theoretical explanation for MIT as a type of political failure resulting from a lack of structural and institutional reforms (Gill and Kharas, 2007; Ohno, 2009; Kharas and Kohli, 2011). Subsequent studies used absolute middle-income thresholds and empirically linked MIT to a growth slowdown (Eichengreen et al., 2012, 2014; Felipe et al., 2012; Aiyar et al., 2013). In addition, the failure of one country in catching up was measured as the ratio of income per capita relative to that of a developed country (World Bank, 2013; Robertson and Ye, 2015).

Earlier studies defined MIT using (1) absolute and relative approaches based on per capita real GDP and (2) a gradual approach to the phase transition failure. All of the MIT models in the gradual approach featured five stages, which were comparable to the Rostow’s model presented several decades ago (Glawe and Wagner, 2016). An economy might be trapped in the industrialization process and fail to progress to the next stage (e.g. Ohno, 2009; Aoki, 2012; Yulek, 2017). Besides, another interesting concept that was closely tied to MIT was premature deindustrialization. Rodrik (2016) characterized it as an unforeseen slowdown in industrial growth, leading to a significantly earlier shift to the service economy. Recent studies have gained interest in topics, such as trapping into and escaping from MIT.

The MIT countries, identified in well-known studies, were compiled by Glawe and Wagner (2016) in their review article. It was found that many countries were trapped in MIT, although several were able to escape. In East Asia, newly industrialized economies (Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand) were listed among the MIT countries. Meanwhile, Bangladesh attained the World Bank’s LMC status in 2015 and recorded a high growth rate of more than 8% by the end of 2010s (MOF, 2022). Likewise, the government set “Vision 2041” to transform this densely populated (1,200 people per square kilometer of land area in 2015) LMC into an HIC in 26 years (BPC, 2020). However, the question arises of whether Bangladesh, like a few other Asian economies, will fall into MIT.

Meanwhile, MIT has been incorporated in several studies on the Bangladesh economy. Using growth forecasts, Alamgir (2014) claimed that with further success in the growth drivers, Bangladesh might become an HIC by 2040–2050. In another study, Rahman and Bari (2016) identified a few push factors for some MIT countries using the findings of a few time series-based studies. They also provided policies and growth gaps for Bangladesh to escape or avoid potential MIT. Subsequently, Ahmed and Chowdhury (2017) estimated total factor productivity (TFP) growth and provided a positive finding for “Vision 2041.” However, no studies have yet provided progress and growth forecasts for the Bangladesh economy based on relevant MIT models.

In addition to identifying transition opportunities to the HIC, it is critical to investigate a few development pitfalls associated with MIT. Bangladesh was not deindustrialized until 2015, and will not happen until 2031, according to the government projections (Andreoni and Tregenna, 2018; BPC, 2020). This premature deindustrialization might lead to MIT (Rodrik, 2016). Earlier, Hausmann et al. (2005) argued that the industrial policies, rather than the typical market reforms, helped the economy overcome MIT and contribute to long-term growth. Moreover, the institutional agenda was related to the transition phase in the MIT model (Glawe and Wagner, 2016; Yulek, 2017). In this regard, there was a scope to integrate a vision-based growth path and forecasts for the Bangladesh economy into relevant MIT models, combining deindustrialization thought and policy-institutional agendas.

This study aims to assess Bangladesh’s economic potential for escaping prospective MIT, with two specific objectives: (1) evaluate the growth path and transition potentiality using selected MIT models and (2) investigate development policies and institutional issues relating to subsequent transitions to the HIC. This paper is divided into five sections following the introduction. Section 2 describes the methodology of selecting relevant MIT models and data collection. The results and discussion are presented in the two sections that follow. While Section 3 analyzes the economic prospect within the framework of different MIT models, Section 4 describes policy-institutional strengths and challenges associated with escaping MIT. Finally, Section 5 concludes with a few limitations.

2. Methodology

This study used three MIT models, which were selected after being compared to several well-known models’ important features and indicators. It determines whether or not the Bangladeshi economy would be trapped in MIT. In addition to the observed data, certain forecasted data were collected and subsequently matched to the selected models. It also identifies challenges Bangladesh has in avoiding MIT.

2.1 Selection of the relevant MIT model

Table 1 presents key features and indicators of different approaches using well-known MIT definitions. Glawe and Wagner (2016) reviewed several absolute and relative definitions using Y/N time series in US$ or PPP$ at constant prices either from Penn World Tables or the Maddison database. If not stated otherwise, Y stands for real GDP, N for population, (Y/N) for real GDP per capita and the g(Y/N) for (Y/N) growth rate. A few absolute definitions are examined, including those of Eichengreen et al. (2012, 2014), Felipe et al. (2012) and Aiyar et al. (2013). Eichengreen et al. (2012, 2014) and Aiyar et al. (2013) estimated MIT using the (Y/N) time series for selected countries. Given that Bangladesh became an LMC several years ago, it cannot be bounded into time series with the limited available discrete forecasts. On the other hand, Felipe et al.’s (2012) model, which is chosen for this study, provided growth rate and time length dimensions for escaping MIT at both the LMC and UMC levels.

The relative approach used a few eminent models like those from the World Bank (2013), Bulman et al. (2014), and Robertson and Ye (2015). Each of them was based on the (Y/N) ratio of a country to the USA and its length. Robertson and Ye (2015) identified MIT based only on time series analysis that cannot be used with projections. In contrast to other empirical research, the World Bank (2013) ranked China as MIT. Bulman et al.’s (2014) model set the constant PPP$-based middle-income threshold of (Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA ranging between 10% and 50% for 49 years. Their findings, which are more applicable to this study, were also linked to industrial transformation and TFP growth in escaping MIT.

In the gradual approach and all the five-stage models, MIT was described as the failure of transition from the third to the fourth stage. The models of Ohno (2009) and Yulek (2017) placed minimal emphasis on the mathematical underpinning and did not specify stage lengths for the sample countries. However, Aoki (2012) divided phases for China, South Korea and Japan using more quantitative metrics and integrated institutional reforms into phases. Moreover, Aoki’s phases were more closely tied to economic transformation theories and terminologies. In this regard, this study uses Aoki’s model.

2.2 Defining indicators for Aoki’s MIT model

According to Aoki’s model, the phases are Malthusian (M), government-led (G), Kuznets (K), human capital-based (H) and post-demographic transition (PD). Table 2 lists the characteristics and indicators associated with each phase. The M-phase was agrarian, labor-intensive and subsistence-oriented. Later, through the government’s industrial accumulation, agrarian employment shifted in the G-phase. The subsequent rapid shift of employment to the industries resulted in higher growth of both the GDP and industrial output in the K-phase. However, the H-phase achieved sustainable industrial growth endogenous to the TFP and human quality. Finally, the PD-phase appeared in the post-demographic transition state. Aoki (2012), in his model, stated that an economy would fall into MIT if the transition from the K-phase to the H-phase failed.

Aoki (2012) used several metrics, such as growth in the GDP per capita, growth of the working-age population, the ratio of sectoral employment, industrial output per worker and the TFP growth rate. Besides, this study added other proxies depending on the phase characteristics and the author’s view. For example, the demand for workers in ten skill-demanding planned sectors was added as an indicator. These sectors include construction, ready-made garments, textile, agro-processing, healthcare, IT and hospitality, leather, light engineering and shipbuilding.

2.3 Data sources and analytical tools

This research used secondary data in retrospect, as well as some forecasts. Bangladesh government data were gathered from statistical reports, perspective plans and institutional websites. For example, the second perspective plan (2021–2041) visualized projections with the “Vision 2041” realized. Other forecasts were considered including those from PricewaterhouseCoopers (PwC, London), the Centre for Economics and Business Research (CEBR, London), the Asian Productivity Organization (APO, Tokyo), the Hong Kong Shanghai Banking Corporation (HSBC) and a few others. In addition, world development indicators (WDI) and demographic data were collected from UN agency websites. Later, the current state and prospects of the Bangladesh economy were presented using selected MIT models, while using a few proxy indicators to supplement the existing forecasted data.

Some of Aoki’s indicators, such as industrial output and employment, were found to be consistent with Rodrik’s theory of premature deindustrialization. In this case, a sample country with a negative trend in industrial value-addition and employment during the K-phase might be stuck in MIT. Besides, policy reforms and institutional strength with respect to the prospective MIT were implemented. Moreover, their progress was tracked using global indices and linked to challenges associated with the subsequent transition.

3. Matching the “vision 2041” of Bangladesh with selected MIT models

Bangladesh’s government aimed to upgrade the country’s fast-growing economy to an HIC in 2041 and a safe delta in 2100 (ICLDS, 2021). Could its vision-based plan ensure a fast growth path for escaping MIT? Will the government’s projections be comparable to those of international agencies? This section summarizes the progress made so far, as well as a few other forecasts based on selected MIT models.

3.1 The economic outlook aligned with absolute and relative MIT definitions

After 44 years of independence, Bangladesh reached LMC status with a GDP per capita of $1,221. Meanwhile, the government initiated planned development to achieve HIC status with an income per capita of $17,221 in the current prices in 2041 (BPC, 2020). Bangladesh, with a high level of social growth for its per capita income, might not achieve the targets of the perspective plan, according to HSBC forecasts (HSBC, 2018; BPC, 2020). However, in 2021, it would reach a lower (Y/N) than the UMC threshold of $5,500 in 2017 US dollars. The spillover gap from the HIC threshold might be wider in 2041 (CEBR, 2021). Table 3 shows the economic outlook aligned with absolute and relative MIT definitions.

According to Felipe et al. (2012), the MIT escaping frontier is set at g(Y/N) ≥ 4.7% in ≤28 years at the LMC level, and g(Y/N) ≥ 3.5% in ≤14 years at the UMC level. In this regard, Bangladesh might fail to meet the UMC threshold of 3.8% g(Y/N) during 2021–2030 (PwC, 2022). Even if it becomes a UMC after 2041, it will not be recognized as an MIT at the LMC level. Such an argument is the result of being indecisive about the length dimension. In this regard, Bangladesh would be far from the HIC vision with a projected g(Y/N) of 4.1% between 2031 and 2040 (CEBR, 2021; BPC, 2020).

According to Bulman et al. (2014), the relative income ratio such as (Y/N)BD/(Y/N)USA should range between 10% and 50%, in less than 49 years to avoid MIT. Bangladesh, at the time of the transition to MC, had 6.8% of the per capita GDP of the US, which might rise to 10.8% in 2030 and to 14% in 2040 (PwC, 2022). In this regard, it would remain far below the MIT escaping threshold in 2041. This economy may not reach the (Y/N)BD/(Y/N)USA limit of 50% even 49 years after the end of the demographic dividend in 2047 (Bulman et al., 2014; UN-DESA, 2022). However, Bangladesh had a high-potential economy, accounting for less than 10% of the US GDP per capita in 2019. During 2010 and 2019, it had the highest annual catch-up rate of ≥3% in Asia for an increased contribution of investment demand to growth (APO, 2021). Along with the demographic dividend, Bangladesh may reduce the gap between planned and actual investment. Moreover, Bulman et al. (2014) linked MIT with TFP growth, which was added in subsequent discussions in conjunction with Aoki’s model.

3.2 Retrospect and prospect using Aoki’s MIT model

Bangladesh was long suppressed during both the British colonial (1757–1947) and the Pakistani (1947–1970) regimes. It emerged as a new nation in 1971. While it failed to achieve an original condition state until the 1980s, it had rapid growth in the 2010s (Mujeri, 2004; BPC, 2020). Figure 1 depicts the retrospect and prospect of the Bangladesh economy, as well as the predicted year for the next transition based on Aoki’s phases. Similarly, phase transitions are discussed using the figure’s data sources.

3.2.1 The M-phase (until 1993)

Even after its independence, Bangladesh’s economy endured low and stationary growth. The g(Y/N) ratio was 0.87% in the 1960s and −0.63% in the 1970s. Until 1965, the (Ea/E) was greater than 80%, with a g(N) of 2.96% during 1965–1970. Subsequently, the g(N) fell to 2.20% during 1990–1995, while its g(Y/N) trended upward. Meanwhile, Bangladesh managed to avoid the Malthusian trap and remained in the M-phase until 1993.

3.2.2 The G-phase (1994–2014)

The Bangladesh economy maintained a moderate g(Y/N) of 2.46% during the 1990s, which increased to 3.95% in the 2000s. In the 2010s, the g(TFP) became positive. Meanwhile, the Ea/E dropped from 68.1% in 1993 to 44.3% in 2014. The capital deepening, or the share of (K/Lh) into the g(Y/Lh), was more contributive, rising from 1.5% during 1990–1995 to 3.3% during 2005–2010. Moreover, the Ei/E increased from less than 10% in the mid-1990s to more than 19% in 2014. Meanwhile, the industrialization efforts accelerated over time, with the ADPi peaking at 4.55% in 2014. Besides, the Gsi/Gs soared to 79.7% in 2007, before dropping to 61.7% in 2013. In this regard, Bangladesh was classified as being in the G-phase during 1994–2014.

3.2.3 The K-phase (2015–2028 anticipated)

The K-phase was characterized by a rapid shift in employment in the industrial and service sectors. The g(Y) in Bangladesh was 6.7% during 2014–2018, which is forecasted to increase to 7.3% during 2018–2023 and 7% during 2023–2028. The labor demand is projected to rise, with the (E10p/E) increasing from 22.2% in 2016 to 35% in 2025, and remaining static thereafter. The g(Y/Lh) was at 3.3% during 2010–2015 and is forecasted to be 6.4% during 2025–2030. Besides, the g(TFP) is forecasted to be 0.62% for the 2020s, higher than the 0.23% in the 2010s. However, capital deepening was not expected to be more contributive beyond 2020, implying that labor quality would not support increased g(Y) after 2028. In this regard, Bangladesh is anticipated to complete the K-phase by 2028.

3.2.4 The H-phase (anticipating 2029–2047)

The g(Y) in 2018 US dollars is forecasted at 7.2% for the period 2028–2033, but it might increase at a slower rate later. The g(Y) in real term is predicted to be higher in the 2030s than in the 2040s. Meanwhile, the demographic dividend would come to an end when the g(N15-64) reached zero in 2047. In this regard, Bangladesh is anticipated to be in the H-phase during 2029–2047.

3.2.5 The PD-phase (anticipating 2048 – next)

With a negative g(N15-54), the PD-phase is anticipated to begin in 2048. The population growth rate will also turn negative within a few years.

The development phases for Bangladesh were identified using forecasts from other agencies rather than the government’s projections. The perspective plan was ready for publication at the beginning of the COVID-19 pandemic, whereas international forecasts were released during the pandemic. Deindustrialization was not included in the Bangladesh government’s plan before 2031. It was not an issue, until 2021, when the K-phase of increasing the share of industrial and employment was visible in the World Bank (2022). However, the shortage of skilled workers has been identified as one of the critical growth barriers in practically all sectors (SEIP, 2017). In earlier research, Bangladesh’s economic growth was regarded as not sustainable with factor accumulation and was instead dependent on increasing TFP growth in the long run (Rao and Hassan, 2011). Furthermore, an apparent slowdown in growth may result in premature deindustrialization and a delayed transition to the H-phase.

Despite suffering significant economic losses during the pandemic, Bangladesh ranked ninth among 66 emerging economies in the wake of the pandemic according to the Economist report (ICLDS, 2021). However, the subsequent Russia–Ukraine war in 2022 caused a global fuel and food crisis, resulting in a larger current account deficit, negative growth in remittances and pressure on Bangladesh’s foreign reserves (Raihan, 2022). How much would a developing economy need to overcome sequential losses from the global crisis? If Bangladesh is trapped in an MIT at the UMC level even in the 2030s, it may not be surmounted after the demographic dividend ends in 2047. In this regard, Bangladesh might fall into MIT and enter into the PD-phase with a per capita income far below the HIC threshold.

4. Institutional and policy issues with the new transition

Bangladesh’s economy was anticipating a new transition from the K-phase to the H-phase. Meanwhile, its industrial policies and institutional framework underwent a series of adjustments. This section explores some of the changes and challenges in economic policies and institutional strength that occurred throughout prior and potential phase transitions. However, the subsequent discussion is narrowed down to the post-independence period due to past colonial and semi-colonial episodes.

4.1 Industrial policies changes and challenges

Since its pre-independence era, Bangladesh has been a trade-protected area, with raw jute as a major export item. In the 1950s, a few jute mills were established. In 1972, the government of the new nation embraced a socialistic policy and moved into state-led industrialization (Salim, 2003). In 1975, the brutal assassination of the nation’s father sealed the fate of the war-torn nation. It stifled the natural passion to escape repression and hunger (ICLDS, 2021). Figure 2 depicts the changes in policies linked to Bangladesh’s economic and industrial development. It was reported that the military government undertook capitalistic policies in the late 1970s. In 1983, the government established the first export-processing zone (EPZ) to create goods for exports but not for the domestic market. Later, since the 1980s, policies for privatization, liberalization and deregulation facilitated the development of an import-centric domestic market (Salim, 2003).

Bangladesh, on the other hand, had a success story of the green revolution with both supportive and reform-embedded policies over the M-phase (Akanda, 2008). Nonetheless, until the early 1990s, all industrialization incentives and efforts were ineffective due to sick industry syndrome (Salim, 2003). Through extensive liberalization and democratic restoration, this economy later achieved an initial condition state in the G-phase (Mujeri, 2004). Moreover, reform initiatives in the 1990s enhanced the TFP (Rao and Hassan, 2011). However, export-oriented garments used to operate on a value-addition system comparable to EPZs, with backward linkages limited to yarns and buttons. In the 2000s, subsequent new industrial structures included telecommunications, durables assembly and industrial conglomerates (Quibria, 2019). The government, since the late 2000s, started executing the power sector master plan and implementing massive infrastructure projects. Besides, special economic zones and high-tech parks were incorporated into public industrial infrastructure (MOF, 2013, 2022). These public efforts fostered a national “Can-Do” spirit in Bangladesh, which was similar to the Korean strong industrialization policy along with the rural “Can-Do” campaigns in the 1960s and 1970s (Yoon, 1985).

Bangladesh, in the K-phase, established new industrialization priorities. In this regard, the predicted transition to H-phase is contingent on demand-driven human resources. Meanwhile, a second perspective plan with initiatives for ICT-based product innovation and job creation in smart and industry 4.0 was developed (BPC, 2020). It is comparable to the South Korean policies of demand-led innovation and high-tech industrialization in the Korean H-phase (Aoki, 2012). Regrettably, previous policies in good governance, anti-corruption, democratization, institutional strengthening and others had ineffective results (Asadullah et al., 2014). Despite this, the Bangladesh government established and intended to establish further institutions and commissions supportive of the H-phase. However, this unfortunate trend of poor policy must not continue in the future.

4.2 Institutional strengths and challenges ahead

This part assesses Bangladesh’s institutional strength using scores from key global indices such as the government effectiveness index (GEI), corruption perception index (CPI), global competitiveness index (GCI), GCI for institutions (GCI: Inst.), democracy index (DI) and fractionalized elites index (FEI). Table 4 shows the attributes of six indices and their scores for Bangladesh throughout the transition from the G-phase to the K-phase. All indices, except FEI, are progressively better at interpreting the best condition at the highest score.

During 2009–2020, Bangladesh had weak and static bureaucratic effectiveness, with a GEI score of around −0.75. Furthermore, public offices remained corrupted, with roughly similar CPI scoring 26 out of 100 during the transition from G-phase to K-phase. Moreover, this nation remained inferior to the LMCs with a lower mean score. With public efforts, how could this developing economy with a demographic dividend ensure sufficient human skills in the face of bureaucratic weakness and extensive corruption? Moreover, even with an increased GCI from the late G-phase to the early K-phase, Bangladesh had weak business competitiveness leaning toward prosperity. However, it had almost identical low scores in institutional CGI, indicating that stakeholders were hesitant to interact with institutions. Democratic practice in Bangladesh was hybrid, resembling the LMC level. Furthermore, political groups and institutions were severely fragmented and unstable as shown by an extremely high FEI score of 9.42 out of 10 in 2020.

Unfortunately, Bangladesh failed in strengthening institutions related to civic activity, democratization, the business environment, anti-corruption and social integration. The vision-led perspective plan was anticipated to be reliant on a fourfold institutional framework as well as capacity building. However, proper governance could not be ensured after the transition to the K-phase. Since 2018, the anti-corruption campaign was ineffective, even with a “zero-tolerance” policy. Given the prior tendency, it may not be anticipated that better quality institution will arise sooner. Is it tough to ensure massive reforms and transformations over the next two decades? However, the government may be forced to act with a strong political will to revitalize institutions.

5. Conclusions

Bangladesh, the world’s fastest-growing LMC, might fail in catching up to a UMC in 2031 or an HIC in 2041. This study examined (1) the growth path and potentials following selected MIT models, and (2) the institutional and policy strengths related to the perspective transition in the Bangladesh’s economy. In this regard, the MIT models of Felipe et al. (2012), Bulman et al. (2014) and Aoki (2012) were chosen representing absolute, relative and gradual approaches, respectively. In absolute and relative definitions, the indicators used were real GDP per capita, its growth and its time length. Aoki (2012) divided MIT into development phases and separated them with specific metrics. Aside from the stipulated indicators, a few other indicators were added depending on phase attributes and the author’s view. This analysis relied mostly on forecasted data rather than on government sources to avoid self-articulation.

Bangladesh may not reach the UMC threshold of $5,500 in 2017 US dollars in 2031. However, even after becoming a UMC in 2041, it would not be trapped at the LMC level. In this regard, Bangladesh would be far from the HIC vision in 2041, with a wider income gap. In terms of real GDP per capita relative to the United States, it would even fall far short of the defined UMC threshold limit in 2041. However, Bangladesh would not fall into an MIT with a length limit of 42 years in Felipe et al.’s (2012) and 49 years in Bulman et al.’s (2014) models, but it might be trapped at the UMC level after the ending of the demographic dividend in 2047.

Bangladesh entered the M-phase in 1993, the G-phase in 2014 and the K-phase according to Aoki’s model. Meanwhile, the Bangladesh government implemented several strategies and established new institutions for development planning. This economy was supposed to reach a peak in industrialization in 2035, with increasing labor productivity. However, capital deepening may not be as beneficial after 2020. Moreover, a lack of human skills combined with a series of global crises resulted in an economic crisis. Any cut-off in projected growth was attributed to a slowdown in industrial growth, leading to premature deindustrialization. In this regard, Bangladesh may enter an MIT before transitioning to the H-phase and reach the PD-phase with a lower per capita income than the HIC threshold.

Notably, “Vision 2041” was subjective to a fourfold institutional pillar, notwithstanding the government’s failure to strengthen institutions. However, rapid reforms may not result in better institutions, as seen by previous trends in indicators of good governance, anti-corruption, democratization and capacity building. The challenge was whether such a poor institutional framework could enable complications with the transition to the H-phase. It should be noted that the subsequent global crisis from the COVID-19 pandemic and the Ukraine war may trigger a long growth slowdown. The government, on the other hand, must have no choice, but to ensure the creation of vibrant institutions and the application of demographic dividends. This study was based on secondary data from different agencies, with no forecasting by the author. Moreover, the data were not sufficient for some models’ indicators. Further research might attempt to incorporate additional models to enrich the findings.

Figures

Phases of economic development for Bangladesh as of Aoki’s MIT model

Figure 1

Phases of economic development for Bangladesh as of Aoki’s MIT model

Industrial development policies along Aoki’s phases for Bangladesh

Figure 2

Industrial development policies along Aoki’s phases for Bangladesh

Selection of MIT models based on key researchers in different approaches

Approach/authorMIT definitions *Indicator and dataKey featuresRemark
Absolute approach
Aiyar et al. (2013)MIT if the g(Y/N) drops for 10 years or more
Residual growth (actual – predicted); RG (t − 1) > RG (t) > RG (t + 1)
(Y/N) in 2005 US$, where Y = real GDP, N = population (1955–2009)
  • (a) Estimated growth using time series

  • (b) Residuals varied greatly from year to year

Felipe et al. (2012)MIT if LMC period > 28 years; g(Y/N) < 4.7%; UMC period >14 years; g(Y/N) < 3.5%(Y/N) in 1990 PPP$, (1950–2010)
  • (a) Distinct traps for the LMC and UMC

  • (b) Two-dimensional limits for growth rate and duration

Selected
Eichengreen et al. (2012, 2014)MIT if (Y/N) > US$ 10,000; g(Y/N) during (t, t − 7) ≥ 3.5%; g(Y/N) during (t, t − 7) – g(Y/N) during (t, t + 7) ≥ 2%(Y/N) in 2005 US$, (1957–2010)
  • (a) Compared growth to lagged years

  • (b) Slowdown on the eve of HIC transition

Relative approach
World Bank (2013)Toward MIT if (Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA ranges between 5% and 45% for 50 years(Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA in log of 1990s US$, (1960–2008)
  • (a) China is in MIT which is different from other empirical studies

Bulman et al. (2014)Toward MIT if (Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA ranges between 10% and 50% for 49 years(Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA in 2005 PPP$, (1960–2009)
  • (a) Rapid industrial transition

  • (b) Higher TFP growth for escapee

Selected
Robertson and Ye (2015)Toward MIT if (Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA ranges between 8% and 36%; Time invariant gap(Y/N)i/(Y/N)USA in 2005 PPP$, (1950–2010)
  • (a) MIT time series definition

  • (b) Income gap log

Gradual approach
Ohno (2009)MIT is seen as industrial growth stagnation for not internalizing parts and components, in the third of the five stagesStage-specific indicators: (Mostly qualitative, i.e. macro and industrial)
Historical data
  • (a) Stages not shown for sample countries

  • (b) Poor mathematical foundation

Aoki (2012)MIT is seen as growth and reform stagnation for not reaching human capital-based development, in the third of the five stagesStage-specific indicators (Mostly quantitative: i.e. macro and industrial)
Historical data
  • (a) Stages separated for Japan, South Korea and China

  • (b) Added institutional development

Selected
Yulek (2017)MIT is seen as growth stagnation for weak technical capability, in the third of the five stagesStage-specific indicators (mostly qualitative, i.e. industrial policies)
Post-IR period data
  • (a) Stages not shown for any countries

  • (b) No mathematical basis

Note(s): (*): (Y/N) stood for real GDP per capita, g for growth rate, t for a point of time/year, (−) from t for the preceding period, (+) with t for the following period and subscript i for a country (like BD for Bangladesh)

Stages, characteristics and indicators using Aoki’s MIT model

StagesCharacteristicsIndicatorsSymbol
Malthusian (M)
  • a.

    Low and stationary per capita GDP

GDP per capita growth rateg(Y/N)
  • b.

    Agricultural employment >80%

Share of farm employmentEa/E
  • c.

    Population growth > g(Y/N)

Population growth rateg(N)
Government-led (G)
  • a.

    Industrial accumulation of government via subsidies

Share of industrial subsidiesGsi/Gs
ADP allocation for industriesADPi
  • b.

    Moderate growth of income per capita

GDP per capita growth rateg(Y/N)
  • c.

    Shifting employment from agriculture to industries

Share of industrial employmentEi/E
Kuznets (K)
  • a.

    High growth of income per capita

GDP growth rateg(Y)
  • b.

    Rapid shift of employment to industries

Share of employment in ten major planned sectorsE10p/E
  • c.

    High growth in industrial output

Labor productivity growthg(Yi/Lh)
Capital deepening g(Yi/Lh)K/Lh in g(Yi/Lh)
Human capital-based (H)
  • a.

    Agricultural employment <20%

Share of farm employmentEa/E
  • b.

    Sustainable growth endogenous to the TFP and human capital

TFP growthg(TFP)
  • c.

    Demographic dividend peak at the end

Growth rate of working age populationg(N15-64)
Post-demographic transition (PD)
  • a.

    Growth dependent on stationary and the least fertility rate

Population growth rateg(N)
  • b.

    Growth dependent on high TFP growth

TFP growthg(TFP)

Note(s): 1: Capital letter notations; Y = real GDP, K = capital, E = employment, N = population, Lh = labor hours, G = government spending, ADP = annual development program, TFP = total factor productivity

2: Small letters; g = growth rate, a = agriculture, i = industry, s = subsidies and 10p = 10 planned sectors

Source(s): Aoki (2012) and author’s view from the characteristics of each phase

Economic outlook of Bangladesh related to absolute and relative MIT definitions

Year(Y/N) at current US$ as of “vision 2041”g(Y) at 2018 US$(Y/N) at 2016 US$(Y/N) at 2016 PPP$g(Y/N) at 2016 PPP$(Y/N)BD/(Y/N)USA at 2016 PPP$
2015; LMC year1,2213,9006.8%
20202,0541,9034,8005.7% (2016–2020)8.0%
20253,2717.3% (2018–2023)3,1076,0009.5%
20305,3387.0% (2023–2028)4,4987,1003.8% (2021–2030)10.8%
Remark (in the 16th LMC year)A vision of a UMC with 5,906 US$<8.9% planned rate<5,500$ UMC threshold at 2017 US$Low as of PPP$ data<4.7% limit as of Felipe et al. (2012)>10% limit as of Bulman et al. (2014)
20358,9477.2% (2028–2033)6,7028,60012.2%
204117,22910,500 (2040)4.1% (2031–2040)14% (2040)
RemarkA vision of an HIC in 2041<planned rate 9.9%<HIC threshold; Larger gap<HIC thresholdSpillover gap since the 2020s<50%; 26 years against ≤49
SourcesBPC (2020)HSBC (2018)CEBR (2021)PwC (2022)PwC (2022)PwC (2022)

Key global indices, their attributes, scores and institutional development in Bangladesh over the transition from the G to K-phase

SlIndexIndicatorAttributes along the scaleScore for BangladeshInstitutional strength
(Number)(Max. score ≥ categorical appraisal ≥ min. score)2009–20142015–2020(Late G to early K phase)
1GEI47Effectiveness of bureaucracy/institutions; 2.5 ≥ strong > weak ≥ (−) 2.5(−) 0.77(−) 0.74Weak and static; inferior to the LMCs as of mean score
2CPI8Public offices; 100 ≥ less corrupt > 49 ≥ more corrupt ≥ 025.5026.17More corrupted but improving; inferior to the LMCs
3GCI110Institutions, policies and factors expediting competitiveness; 7 ≥ strong > weak ≥ 13.673.82Weak position leaning toward prosperity; similar to the LMCs
4GCI: Inst20Stakeholders interacting with institutions; 7 ≥ reliable > dubious ≥ 13.153.16Dubious stakeholders; inferior to the LMCs
5DI6010 ≥ full democracy > 8 ≥ flawed > 6 ≥ hybrid > 4 authoritarian ≥ 05.855.72Hybrid democracy; similar to the LMCs
6FEI14Political groups and institutions; 10 ≥ unstable > stable ≥ 08.979.45Severely unstable; inferior to the LMCs

References

Ahmad, I. (1972), “Unemployment and underemployment in Pakistan”, Retrospective theses and dissertations 5201, Iowa State University Digital Repository, available at: https://lib.dr.iastate.edu/rtd/5201

Ahmed, M. and Chowdhury, T.T. (2017), “Total factor productivity in Bangladesh: an analysis using data from 1981-2014”, BIDS Research Alamac 2017, Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies, Dhaka.

Aiyar, S., Duval, R., Puy, D., Wu, Y. and Zhang, L. (2013), “Growth slowdowns and the middle-income trap”, IMF working paper # WP/13/71, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Akanda, M.A.I. (2008), “Evolution of agricultural policies prioritizing the development of land-poor farmers in Bangladesh”, Journal of Rural Development, Vol. 28 No. 4, pp. 419-437.

Alamgir, M. (2014), “Vision 2030 - avoiding the middle-income trap and jobless growth”, Bangladesh Economists Forum, Dhaka, available at: http://www.pri-bd.org/upload/file/bef_paper/1414213335.pdf (accessed 21-22 June 2014).

Andreoni, A. and Tregenna, F. (2018), “Stuck in the middle: premature deindustrialization and industrial policy”, CCRED working paper # 11/2018, Centre for Competition, Regulation and Economic Development, Johannesburg.

Aoki, M. (2012), “The five-phases of economic development and institutional evolution in China, Japan and Korea”, in Aoki, M., Kuran, T. and Roland, G. (Eds), Institutions and Comparative Economic Development, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 13-47.

APO (2021), APO Productivity Data Book 2021, Asian Productivity Organization, Tokyo.

Asadullah, M.N., Savoia, A. and Mahmud, W. (2014), “Paths to development: is there a Bangladesh surprise?”, World Development, Vol. 62, pp. 138-154.

BPC (2020), Making Vision 2041 a Reality: Perspective Plan of Bangladesh 2021-2041, Bangladesh Planning Commission, Dhaka.

Bulman, D., Eden, M. and Nguyen, H. (2014), “Transitioning from low-income growth to high-income growth: is there a middle-income trap?”, Policy research working paper # 7104, World Bank, Washington, DC.

CEBR (2021), Macroeconomic Forecasting: World Economic League Table 2022, Centre for Economics and Business Research, London, available at: https://cebr.com/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/WELT-2022.pdf (accessed 12 March 2022).

Eichengreen, B., Park, D. and Shin, K. (2012), “When fast-growing economies slow down: international evidence and implications for China”, Asian Economic Papers, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 42-87.

Eichengreen, B., Park, D. and Shin, K. (2014), “Growth slowdowns redux”, Japan and the World Economy, Vol. 32, pp. 65-84.

EIU (2022), Democracy Index 2021, The Economists Intelligence Unit, London.

Felipe, J., Abdon, A. and Kumar, U. (2012), “Tracking the middle-income trap: what is it, who is in it, and why?”, Working paper No. 715, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, New York.

Gill, I. and Kharas, H. (2007), An East Asian Renaissance – Ideas for Economic Growth, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Glawe, L. and Wagner, H. (2016), “The middle-income trap: definitions, theories and countries concerned - a literature survey”, Comparative Economic Studies, Vol. 58 No. 4, pp. 507-538.

Hausmann, R., Lant, P. and Rodrik, D. (2005), “Growth accelerations”, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 10, pp. 303-329.

HSBC (2018), The World in 2030: HSBC Global Research, HSBC Bank, London.

ICLDS (2021), Jonmo Shotoborshe Udiyoman Bangladesh (Emerging Bangladesh on the Century of the Birth of Bangabandhu), Institute of Conflict Law and Development Studies, Dhaka.

Kharas, H. and Kohli, H. (2011), “What is the middle-income trap, why do countries fall into it, and how can it be avoided?”, Global Journal of Emerging Market Economies, Vol. 3 No. 3, pp. 281-289.

MOF (2013), Bangladesh Economic Review 2012, Ministry of Finance, Dhaka.

MOF (2022), Bangladesh Economic Review 2022, Ministry of Finance, Dhaka.

Mujeri, M.K. (2004), “Changes in policy framework and total factor productivity growth in Bangladesh”, Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 30 Nos 3 and 4, pp. 1-29.

Ohno, K. (2009), “Avoiding the middle-income trap – renovation industrial policy formulation in Vietnam”, ASEAN Economic Bulletin, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 25-43.

PwC (2022), The World in 2050, PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, London, available at: https://www.pwc.com/gx/en/research-insights/economy/the-world-in-2050.html

Quibria, M.G. (2019), Bangladesh’s Road to Long-Term Economic Prosperity: Risks and Challenges, Palgrave McMillan, Cham.

Rahman, M. and Bari, E. (2016), Escaping the Middle-Income Trap: Perspectives from Bangladesh, Centre for Policy Dialogue (CPD) and Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Bangladesh Office, Dhaka.

Raihan, S. (2022), “Global economic slowdown and the Bangladesh economy”, SANEM Thinking Aloud, Vol. 9 No. 2, p. 1.

Rao, B.B. and Hassan, G. (2011), “Determinants of the long-run growth rate of Bangladesh”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 18 No. 7, pp. 655-658.

Robertson, P.E. and Ye, L. (2015), “On the existence of a middle-income trap”, Working paper # 13/12, University of Western Australia, Crawley.

Rodrik, D. (2016), “Premature deindustrialization”, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 1-33.

Salim, R.A. (2003), “Economic liberalization and productivity growth: further evidence from Bangladesh”, Oxford Development Studies, Vol. 31 No. 1, pp. 85-98.

SEIP (2017), “BIDS study report on labour market and skill gap in Bangladesh”, Skills for Employment Investment Program, Finance Division, Ministry of Finance, Dhaka.

UN-DESA (2022), World Population Prospects 2022, Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations, available at: https://population.un.org/wpp/ (accessed 06 July 2022).

World Bank (2013), China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative High-Income Society, World Bank, Washington, DC.

World Bank (2022), Database of the World Development Indicators, World Bank, Washington, DC, available at: https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators (accessed 12 May 2022).

Yoon, I.S. (1985), “South Korea’s industrial environment”, Report # UMTRI-85-42, University of Michigan Transportation Research Institute, Michigan.

Yulek, M.A. (2017), “On the middle-income trap, the industrialization process and appropriate industrial policy”, Journal Industry, Competition and Trade, Vol. 17, pp. 325-348.

Corresponding author

M. Aminul Islam Akanda can be contacted at: akanda_ai@hotmail.com

Related articles