Assessing project risks from a supply chain quality management (SCQM) perspective

Barbara Gaudenzi (Department of Business Administration, University of Verona, Verona, Italy)
Abroon Qazi (School of Business Administration, American University of Sharjah, Sharjah, United Arab Emirates)

International Journal of Quality & Reliability Management

ISSN: 0265-671X

Article publication date: 17 August 2020

Issue publication date: 16 March 2021

4384

Abstract

Purpose

Project-driven supply chain risks pose a significant threat to the success of complex development projects, in terms of achieving key performances such as quality, time and efficiency. The purpose of this paper is to adopt a supply chain quality perspective in order to explore and better understand the unique attributes of risks associated with project-driven supply chains for continuously improving the quality of both processes and products.

Design/methodology/approach

Theoretically grounded in the framework of Bayesian Belief Networks and Game theory, this paper develops a structured process for assessing and managing risks in project-driven supply chains. The application of the proposed approach is demonstrated through a simulation case study conducted on the development project of Boeing 787 aircraft.

Findings

The conflicting incentives amongst stakeholders in a supply chain can jeopardise the success of a project and therefore, assessment of this category of risks classified as “Game theoretic risks” needs special consideration. Project-driven supply chain risks pose a significant threat to the success of complex projects. The results of the study clearly revealed that without mitigating the game theoretic risks, the main objective of timely completion of the Boeing 787 project was not materialised. Further, the lack of management expertise was the major factor contributing to the overall project costs including cost of quality.

Originality/value

The proposed process and analyses present a significant and original insight in terms of capturing the key determinants of both product and service quality such as product performance, convenience and reliability of service, timeliness, ease of maintenance, flexibility, and customer satisfaction and comfort. Propositions are developed for ascertaining the significance of information sharing in a project-driven supply chain, and a fair sharing partnership is introduced to help supply chain managers in managing game theoretic risks in order to achieve the goals of quality, time and efficiency.

Keywords

Citation

Gaudenzi, B. and Qazi, A. (2021), "Assessing project risks from a supply chain quality management (SCQM) perspective", International Journal of Quality & Reliability Management, Vol. 38 No. 4, pp. 908-931. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJQRM-01-2020-0011

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2020, Barbara Gaudenzi and Abroon Qazi

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Supply chains have become more complex and vulnerable due to trends such as globalisation, increased outsourcing, global sourcing, and focus on efficiency (Son and Orchard, 2013). These trends generate the need to create more resilient supply chains (Das, 2018), identifying vulnerabilities and risks within functions and processes, and their impacts on supply chain performances (Mhatre et al., 2017).

Non-linear interactions between risks make it a daunting task to understand and properly manage these risks (Ackermann et al., 2014) and therefore, a number of frameworks and tools have been introduced to the literature on supply chain risk management (SCRM) (Christopher and Peck, 2004) and supply chain quality management (SCQM) (Foster, 2008) to better address the increasing interdependency among supply chain actors, processes and risks. Amongst these approaches, there are, for example, scenario-based analyses (Das, 2018), interpretive structural modelling (Haleem et al., 2012), fuzzy techniques (Nieto-Morote and Ruz-Vila, 2011), Bayesian Belief Networks (BBNs) (Qazi et al., 2018), and the Analytic Hierarchy Process (AHP) (Gaudenzi and Borghesi, 2006).

In SCRM and SCQM frameworks, an interesting area of investigation is project management. According to Mhatre et al. (2017), long-term projects present a high level of complexity, typically emphasising the key role of an effective risk management to achieve the project and supply chain objectives (Doloi et al., 2012; Chapman and Ward, 2004). In the specific case of a new product development (NPD) project, key risks are major delays and cost overruns, which are influenced by significant and complex interdependency between risks, involving different stakeholders and decision-makers (Ackermann et al., 2006, 2014).

Conventional supply chains (involving routine processes) and project-driven supply chains (involving unique processes specific to NPD) are reported to have different characteristics and therefore, there is a need to tailor the risk management process in accordance with the characteristics and objectives of the supply chain. A well-known case in this sense is Boeing, which outsourced 70% of the development and production tasks in the development project of Boeing 787 aircraft (Tang et al., 2009; Zhao et al., 2013). More than 50% of the fuselage was planned to be made of composite material. In order to mitigate the key risks, a strategic partnership was developed with Tier-1 suppliers passing to them the responsibility to control quality and risks associated with the development project. Despite Boeing adopting an unconventional supply chain composed of several partners, the project was delayed incurring major financial penalties in millions of dollars because the project team did not realise the importance of assessing and managing risks before the commencement of the project (Tang et al., 2009). The Boeing management had not planned for managing the interdependency between risks.

BBNs provide an effective modelling framework for capturing interdependency between risks (Qazi et al., 2018). Game theory is a technique, which allows to model situations in which stakeholders have conflicting incentives, and can effectively support risk management decisions (Osborne, 2003). Game theory can be integrated with BBNs in order to capture causal interdependency across risk factors. However, these tools have not been applied together with the scope to modelling and managing risks in complex supply chains where key supply chain stakeholders might have conflicting incentives regarding the key performance attributes. For example, time might not be the top priority for a supplier specific to a supply chain, who is involved in providing supplies to multiple supply chains with different associated contracts and incentivisation schemes. In addition, while interdependency modelling has been extensively explored in other research areas, such as the reliability and safety of engineering systems, there are fewer applications in the area of SCRM, SCQM and complex projects.

The present paper has therefore the scope to propose a framework for capturing interdependency between risks and modelling the risk appetite of a decision maker (Aven, 2015), using the lens of BBNs and Game theory. The framework will be validated through a simulation model (Badurdeen et al., 2014) for the case study of Boeing 787 (Tang et al., 2009). The case study was used to construct cognitive maps followed by the development of BBN and Game theory-based models. This paper also attempts to narrow the aforementioned research gap and aims to extend the research of Mhatre et al. (2017). The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. A brief overview of the relevant literature is presented in Section 2. The proposed methodology is described in Section 3 and demonstrated through a simulation case study in Section 4. We discuss the implications of our study in Section 5 and conclude the article and present future research directions in Section 6.

2. Literature review

There are different perceptions of risk in the context of SCRM and SCQM, and the literature has offered significant theoretical and empirical advancements in the investigation of risk and uncertainty in supply chain operations (Tang and Nurmaya Musa, 2011). For example, researchers highlighted that certifications in Quality Management System, particularly the ISO 9000 and ISO 9001 certifications, represent for organizations a first essential step in order to reach a comprehensive understanding of risks and vulnerabilities amongst companies' processes, and to achieve better performance (Bevilacqua et al., 2013). In particular, these standards might contribute to improving the effectiveness and efficiency of process management within the company and along the network (Su et al., 2020). In parallel, these standards lead organizations to extensively adopt quality tools and techniques (Castello et al., 2020), which can improve the measurement of performances and risks.

Two important aspects in SCRM are the assessment of the probability of risk event and the measurement of its final impact (Colicchia and Strozzi, 2012). SCRM researchers typically focus on the negative consequences of risk (Christopher and Peck, 2004; Wagner and Bode, 2008), which are generally characterised as events with small/medium probability and the potentiality of severe consequences in terms of business continuity and profitability (Christopher and Peck, 2004). Sources of these risks have been addressed in SCQM studies (Das, 2018; Moeinedini et al., 2018; Das, 2018; Roy et al., 2016; Knemeyer et al., 2009) as – for example – natural calamity, terrorism, political instability or labour disputes, and vulnerabilities in single/global sourcing, which can generate cascading effects such as supplier failures, delays and other negative impacts in SC operations.

A review of articles focussing on supply chain risks reveals the need for conducting extensive research in the area of both SCRM and SCQM in order to explore holistic methods for capturing the interdependency between risks (Tang and Nurmaya Musa, 2011; Colicchia and Strozzi, 2012; Ghadge et al., 2012). Existing risk analysis methods assign risks to independent categories and fail to capture the interdependency between causal chains of vulnerabilities, risk sources, risk events and resulting losses; disruptions are unpredictable and in order to safeguard a supply chain from the adverse effects of these disruptions, managers need to have complete visibility across the entire network; and there is a need to explore the synergy of SCRM and quality management for the continuous improvement of supply chain operations (Qazi et al., 2018; Abuazza et al., 2020).

Researchers have been using different techniques for capturing the interdependency between project/supply chain risks. Well-cited techniques include BBNs (Badurdeen et al., 2014; Lockamy, 2014; Garvey et al., 2015; Nepal and Yadav, 2015); Failure Modes and Effects Analysis (FMEA) (Sinha et al., 2004); Network Theory (Squire, 2010; Fang et al., 2012); Monte Carlo Simulation (Lee et al., 2012); AHP (Gaudenzi and Borghesi, 2006); Analytic Network Process (ANP) (Boateng et al., 2015); Causal Mapping (Ackermann et al., 2014); Systems Thinking (Williams, 2005); Graph Theory (Wagner and Neshat, 2010) and ISM (Pfohl et al., 2011). The tools that can significantly contribute to the integration of SCRM and SCQM and to the continuous improvement of processes in SCM are BBNs, FMEA, Causal Mapping and ISM because all these tools help in visualising the causal interdependency among different factors influencing the quality and key performance indicators of a supply chain. BBNs provide a unique opportunity in terms of integrating numerous tools of total quality management such as cause and effect diagrams, pareto analysis, scatter diagrams, and process flow charts.

Strategic risks can result among supply chain stakeholders due to their conflicting incentives such as their unique preferences (utility) across supply chain performance indicators (Wakolbinger and Cruz, 2010; Lutz et al., 2012; Zhao et al., 2012; Zhao, 2013; Xin and Zhao, 2013). Game theory is an effective technique for mitigating such risks (Osborne, 2003). Risk sharing-based contracts can be designed for aligning conflicting incentives of stakeholders to maintain high reliability and profitability of a supply network. According to Qazi et al. (2015), strategic risks have not been fully explored in the literature on SCRM and project risk management and, therefore, there is a need to model opportunistic behaviour of stakeholders while modelling and assessing supply chain risks.

Limited articles have explored supply chain risks associated with projects involving NPD and the literature on project risk management only partially includes risk management frameworks to manage risks related to such mega projects (Kardes et al., 2013). For example, in the construction industry, Aloini et al. (2012) highlighted that none of the 140 research articles on supply chain management in construction projects dealt with the risk management. In the aviation industry, Tang et al. (2009) used secondary data to establish why the Boeing 787 project incurred a substantial financial loss despite Boeing having introduced a fair-sharing partnership with its Tier-1 suppliers. The undermining of the supply chain risks associated with the project was adjudged as the main underlying cause; however, the assessment of risks in isolation might not represent the systemic behaviour of risks (Ackermann et al., 2014). As opposed to utilising secondary data, efforts have been made to conduct case studies in industry and explore the nature of SCRM processes adopted in such projects; however, such studies have either focussed on the conventional risk matrix-based tools thereby assuming independence of risks (Khan et al., 2008) or reported on a single stage of the risk management process without integrating all the stages involved (Lin and Zhou, 2011).

Badurdeen et al. (2014) also conducted a case study in Boeing related to the development project of a missile guidance system. Their proposed model establishes the link between supply chain risks but instead of integrating the network-wide risks, the model captures the risks specific to a Tier-1 supplier and aids in ranking the suppliers as does the model proposed by Hosseini and Barker (2016). It seems that there are two major limitations of the existing studies: first, these studies focus on few stages of the risk management process without establishing and validating a comprehensive risk management process in such projects; and secondly, the interdependency modelling of risks in general and strategic risks in particular is ignored in entirety. As highlighted by Moeinedini et al. (2018), due to the non-repetitive nature of the projects, often characterised by a lack of historical data and domino-effects amongst risks, more investigations and frameworks about project risk assessment are needed. To fill this gap, Qazi et al. (2016) initially introduced a process, namely Project Complexity and Risk Management (ProCRiM) capturing interdependencies among project characteristics, risks and project objectives. In this additional study, authors propose a new methodology grounded in the theoretical framework of BBNs and Game theory, which is presented in the following section. The scope of this study is also to start filling a wider gap, highlighted by Huo et al. (2019), in that the majority of studies on SCQM have considered SCM and QM as different practices without investigating the association between them.

3. Proposed methodology

BBNs with their background in statistics and artificial intelligence were first introduced in the 1980s for dealing with uncertainty in knowledge-based systems (Sigurdsson et al., 2001). They have been successfully used in addressing problems related to a number of diverse specialities including reliability modelling, medical diagnosis, geographical information systems and aviation safety management, among others. (Jensen and Nielsen, 2007; Kjaerulff and Anders, 2008). BBNs facilitate capturing the interdependency between uncertain variables and a number of studies specific to SCRM have substantiated the efficacy of BBNs in modelling supply chain risks (Badurdeen et al., 2014; Garvey et al., 2015).

Game theory was developed to explain the rationale for taking economic decisions that would not have occurred on the basis of a simple cost-benefit analysis. Game theory can help the operations managers take appropriate decisions within the supply chain context. A game in a business setting has four basic elements: players (supply chain stakeholders); rules of the game (policies and constraints); a complete set of actions or decisions for each player; and the outcomes or pay-offs resulting from each set of decisions. For understanding the mechanics of Game theory, interested readers may consult Osborne, 2003 and Zhao et al., 2012.

The proposed process integrating the two techniques of BBNs and Game theory is shown in Figure 1. The process involves identifying key risks, strategies and performance criteria specific to the project-driven supply chain. This step is followed by the qualitative modelling of the BBN model. Game theoretic modelling of the conflicting incentives is carried out through a detailed analysis of available information in the form of policies and/or partnerships. The players are identified and their strategies are established followed by the determination of their pay-offs. Subsequently, game theoretic analysis is performed and optimal strategies are established. The results are incorporated in the BBN model in the form of a small network of “Game theoretic risks”. The “Game theoretic risks” node is connected to the relevant impact node. The entire BBN model is populated with parameters using expert judgement, available data and the results of the game theoretic analysis. Sensitivity analysis of the entire model is performed, and key risks and strategies are established. This analysis helps in validating the quantitative part of the model through involving experts and stakeholders in the validation process.

4. Demonstrative case study

The proposed methodology is demonstrated using secondary data related to the development project of Boeing 787 aircraft (Tang et al., 2009). The Game theory and BBN-based models are presented and analysed in the following sections using the information and data related to the case of Boeing as provided by Tang et al. (2009); Zhao et al. (2013); Xin and Zhao (2013); Denning (2013a, b) and Greising and Johnsson (2007).

4.1 Game theoretic models and analysis

The discrete time-based Game theoretic analysis concerning the development project of Boeing 787 aircraft revealed that there were conflicting incentives amongst the strategic partners (Xin and Zhao, 2013). Developing on this analysis, we propose new game models incorporating uncertainty and the features of present value of money and continuous timeframe. Every project comprises two components of costs; direct and indirect costs. Direct costs relate to each task of the project including costs covering labour, material, shipping, etc. Indirect costs do not relate directly to the tasks but these are linked to the project duration. Overhead, delaying penalty, order cancellations and financial losses are some of the examples of indirect costs. A longer task is considered to lower direct costs while a longer project increases indirect costs.

The direct cost of a task reduces with the duration representing a convex function as shown in Figure 2. “Xi” indicates the scheduled timeframe of the task. If either Boeing or a Tier-1 supplier delays its task, it gets a saving represented by “si”. In the case of expediting the task, there is an associated cost represented by “ci”. The indirect cost of a project increases with the project duration representing a convex function as shown in Figure 2. “Xs” indicates the scheduled timeframe of the suppliers' tasks while “Xm” indicates the scheduled timeframe of the Boeing's task. If the resultant time of the two tasks exceeds the scheduled time, there is a penalty “pi”, whereas expediting the project results in the reward “ri” for each partner.

It is assumed that all the Tier-1 suppliers perform their tasks in parallel and the overall time taken by the suppliers is determined by the supplier completing its task at the end. After the completion of tasks by the suppliers, Boeing performs the final assembling phase.

4.1.1 Strategic loss-sharing partnership

The strategic partnership was introduced by Boeing in order to reduce its financial risks. Each firm was supposed to bear the direct and indirect costs, whereas the final payment was to be made only after the successful culmination of the project. If a firm delays its task and the project gets delayed, all the firms incur additional indirect costs but the delaying firm saves from its direct costs. The firms having completed the tasks in time are unfairly penalised because of the project delay caused by the delaying firm. As the firms were not made responsible exclusively for their specific actions, this type of partnership resulted into a “moral hazard”. There were misaligned objectives as every supplier would consider the possibility of other partner delaying their respective task and in the case of delivering the task in time, the supplier would lose the amount contrary to the delaying suppliers gaining the same. We will present various forms of games in order to analyse the game theoretic perspective of Boeing's partnership.

4.1.1.1 Game between two suppliers with an uncertainty regarding the project completion time

In this game, we consider a situation in which both the suppliers are uncertain about the response of Boeing keeping in view the delay incurred by one of the suppliers (or both). Therefore, in the case of any delay, a node representing “Nature” is introduced having probability “q” denoting the chance of Boeing expediting the project for timely completion as shown in Figure 3. It is evident that “E” is a dominated strategy for both the suppliers.

Lemma 1.

In a loss-sharing partnership between two suppliers and an OEM, the suppliers may either delay or keep their tasks in time under the following conditions:

  1. All the players having complete knowledge of the cost functions of each other

  2. The amount of penalty being greater than the saving resulting from delaying the task

  3. An uncertainty “q” related to the timely completion of the project

DD is the unique Nash equilibrium;

(1)iff1qsi(xs)pi(xs+Xm)

KK is the pareto-optimal solution;

(2)iff1q>si(xs)pi(xs+Xm)

4.1.1.2 Game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of Supplier 2

In this game, we incorporate the uncertainty about the cost function of a supplier. Supplier 1 knows about its pay-offs but cannot differentiate between the two types of Supplier 2; one having the penalty function greater than the saving function (Type L) while the other having converse of it (Type H). Supplier 2 knows about the pay-offs of both of them. The matrix form of the game between Supplier 1 and each of the two types of Supplier 2 is presented in Table 1. For this situation, a pure strategy Nash equilibrium is defined as a triple of actions (Osborne, 2003), one for Supplier 1 and one for each type of Supplier 2, with the property that:

  1. the action of Supplier 1 is optimal, given the actions of the two types of Supplier 2 (and Supplier 1's belief about the state), and

  2. the action of each type of Supplier 2 is optimal, given the action of Supplier 1.

Lemma 2.

In a loss-sharing partnership between two suppliers and an OEM, the suppliers may either delay or keep their tasks in time under the following conditions:

  1. A supplier having an uncertainty about the cost function of other supplier

  2. The amount of penalty being greater than the saving resulting from delaying the task for the supplier having the incomplete information

(K,(K,D)) is the pareto-optimal solution;

(3)iffp>s1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)

(K,(K,D)) and (D,(D,D)) are the Nash equilibria;

(4)iffp=s1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)

(D,(D,D)) is the unique Nash equilibrium;

(5)iffp<s1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)

4.1.1.3 Game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other

We analyse the game between two suppliers incorporating the uncertainty of both suppliers regarding the type of other one in terms of the relative functions of penalty and saving. Both suppliers are uncertain about the pay-offs of each other. Type “L” indicates the supplier having the penalty greater than the corresponding saving while type “H” represents the supplier whose saving is greater than the relative penalty associated with the delay. Supplier 1 has a common belief represented by “p” of being sure about the type “L” of Supplier 2 while the Supplier 2 has a common belief represented by “q” of being sure about the type “L” of Supplier 1. The game is shown in Figure 4. The expected pay-offs of type “L” and type “H” of Supplier 1 are given in Table 2. Each column represents actions of each type of Supplier 2; the first action representing the action of type “L” of Supplier 2 followed by that of type “H” of Supplier 2. For each of the columns, the greater value is selected out of the two actions of Supplier 1. The triple of actions corresponding to each greater value is checked for confirming the best action for each of the two types of Supplier 2. The same procedure is repeated for each of the types of Supplier 2 having expected pay-offs tabulated in Table 2. After considering the results of all four expected pay-off tables, it is revealed that ((D,D),(D,D)) and ((K,D),(K,D)) are the Bayesian Nash equilibria of this game.

Lemma 3.

In a loss-sharing partnership between two suppliers and an OEM, both suppliers will either delay or keep their tasks (in time) under the following conditions:

  1. Both suppliers being uncertain about the cost function of each other

  2. OEM completing its task within the stipulated timeframe

((K,D),(K,D)) and ((D,D),(D,D)) are the Bayes Nash equilibria;

(6)iffps1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)andqs2(x2)p2(xs+Xm)

((K,D),(K,D)) is the pareto-optimal solution;

(7)iffp>s1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)andq>s2(x2)p2(xs+Xm)

((K,D),(K,D)) is the unique Bayes Nash equilibrium in all other cases.

4.1.1.4 Game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other and Boeing's response

The previous game assumed that Boeing would complete its task in time. Now, we incorporate a possibility of Boeing expediting its task (E) but there is an uncertainty associated with the possibility of the project not getting completed in time. The common belief about this uncertainty is represented by “r” as each supplier will have a prior belief that the project would not be completed in time because of the delay in the first phase of the project. The game is presented in Figure 5 with the pay-off matrix shown in Table 3. The Bayesian Nash equilibria of this game are again ((K,D),(K,D)) and ((D,D),(D,D)).

Lemma 4.

In a loss-sharing partnership between two suppliers and an OEM, both suppliers will either delay or keep their tasks under the following conditions:

  1. Both suppliers being uncertain about the cost function of each other

  2. An uncertainty associated with the possibility of OEM expediting its task to cover up the delay caused by the suppliers

((K,D),(K,D)) and ((D,D),(D,D)) are the Bayes Nash equilibria;

(8)iffprs1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)andqrs2(x2)p2(xs+Xm)

((K,D),(K,D)) is the pareto-optimal solution;

(9)iffpr>s1(x1)p1(xs+Xm)andqr>s2(x2)p2(xs+Xm)

((D,D),(D,D)) is the unique Bayes Nash equilibrium in all other cases.

Theorem 1.

In the case of a loss-sharing partnership (between an OEM and Tier-1 suppliers) within a supply chain, all Tier-1 suppliers will either delay or keep their tasks in the case of an uncertainty about the cost functions of one another but the possibility of timely completion of the project is very rare because of the requirement of meeting a very strong probabilistic condition on the part of each supplier. This theorem is valid under the following assumptions:

  1. All Tier-1 Suppliers perform their tasks simultaneously (Phase I).

  2. The OEM undertakes its task after the completion of all the tasks of Tier-1 Suppliers (Phase II).

  3. The project duration is the summation of the two phases.

Let r represent the common belief of the suppliers about the possibility of OEM not expediting its task in order to cover up the delay of Phase I and pij represent the belief of a supplier i about the cost function of other supplier “j” being of the form “pj(xs+Xm)>sj(xj)” (type “L”) with p and s indicating the penalty and cost saving functions, respectively.

Corollary 1.

Each supplier “i” of type “L” will keep their task:

(10)iffj=1N1rpijsi(xi)pi(xs+Xm)
Corollary 2.

((K,D),(K,D),(K,D)N) and ((D,D),(D,D),(D,D)N) are Bayes Nash equilibria.

(11)iffj=1N1rpijsi(xi)pi(xs+Xm)foreverysuppliersioftypeL
Corollary 3.

((D,D),(D,D),(D,D)N) is the unique Bayes Nash equilibrium in all other cases meaning that the project will be delayed even if all suppliers are of type “L”.

These results indicate that in the case of an uncertainty about the cost functions of other suppliers, each supplier might delay their task even knowing that the OEM might not expedite its task in order to cover up the overall project duration. Thus, in a supply chain, an uncertainty about the information of other partners results in the worst selection of actions by all partners. The same phenomenon can be best described as a bullwhip effect. Uncertainty about the information is a major risk within a supply chain that can result into major losses as evident in the case of the Boeing 787 project. After analysing the strategic partnership, it is revealed that the partnership scheme engendered misaligned incentives amongst the stakeholders that finally contributed to the realisation of game theoretic risks. Therefore, there was a need to assess the impact of misaligned incentives classified as “game theoretic risks” on project performance and to introduce a “fair risk-sharing strategy” for mitigating game theoretic risks.

4.2 Bayesian Belief Network models and analysis

Based on the information retrieved from Tang et al. (2009), the perceived oversimplified cognitive map of the Boeing 787 project comprised 27 concepts and 38 links as shown in Figure 6. The model clearly reveals that Boeing was focussing on the opportunities resulting from the introduction of an unproven technology and an unconventional supply chain. After the inferencing stage, the probability of the development time being high was just 0.09 and that of the development cost was 0.22. These favourable results stem from the fact that the Boeing management had ignored the interdependency between risk factors and assumed the events of development cost and time being high as unlikely. Contrary to the expectations, the project was delayed by almost three years causing a major financial penalty to the Boeing.

There were a number of risks associated with the decisions taken by the Boeing management. The cognitive map of the actual supply chain risks comprised 41 concepts and 63 links as shown in Figure 7. A BBN was modelled following the steps outlined in the proposed framework. Two nodes identified earlier as “fair risk-sharing strategy” (see concept 36 in Figure 7) and “game theoretic risks” (see concept 35 in Figure 7) were added to the BBN model. The output of “game theoretic risks” node was linked to the “development time” (see concept 20 in Figure 7) node. The impact of “game theoretic risks” node on the “development time” node was quantified based on the game theoretic analysis. The unproven technology resulted in major technological risks that further affected the intended outcomes. Outsourcing was considered to be a means of reducing development cost and time; however, it resulted in integration issues as the Tier-1 suppliers were not proficient in selecting their suppliers. Furthermore, the strategic partnership was not a fair strategy as it did not provide due incentives to the stakeholders to keep the schedule in time. This caused an increase in the exposure of game theoretic risks, being dominant on other factors affecting the development time.

The management involved in the project was lacking expertise in SCRM. The expertise would have provided a guard against all the risks in terms of adopting suitable mitigation strategies. Game theoretic risks are assumed to be independent of the management expertise as the conventional SCRM process does not focus on analysing the risks caused by misaligned incentives of the stakeholders. It also emphasises the importance of considering this unique category of risks within the project risk assessment stage and the management must possess the ability to apply Game theory to quantify such risks.

The initial updating of the model revealed that the probability of the development cost and time being high was 0.46 and 0.54, respectively. Different scenarios were generated and the impact of individual risk factors was determined as shown in Table 4. Management expertise was found to be the dominant factor influencing both development cost and time. Game theoretic risks were considered as the dominant factor influencing the development time across all scenarios. The proactive strategies of ensuring a team with SCRM expertise, devising a fair strategy, negotiating with the labour union, and adopting a thorough supplier selection process resulted in the probability of development cost and time overruns as 0.31 and 0.30, respectively.

4.3 Formulation of a fair strategy

The sensitivity analysis of game theoretic risks revealed its major impact on the development time. Therefore, there is a requirement of designing a fair strategy in order to reduce the game theoretic risks. The main purpose of a fair strategy is to make each player responsible for their own deeds. If the suppliers perform their tasks within the stipulated time, the consequences of any delay on the part of Boeing would be completely compensated by the Boeing, and in case of suppliers having expedited their tasks, Boeing would have to pay the reward that did not materialise because of its delay. Similarly, if a supplier is involved in the delay, it will be proportionately penalised for its part of the delay. In the case of a delay on the part of both the suppliers and Boeing, the penalty would be paid fairly.

Developing on the fair strategy proposed by Xin and Zhao (2013), we present a modified strategy incorporating the features of the time value of money and the continuous rate of interest. Boeing's and suppliers' pay-off functions considering the time value of money are tabulated in Table 5. Following are the various symbols used in the pay-off functions:

(12)αm=XmxmXm+Xsxsxm
(13)βm=xmXmxm+xsXsXm
(14)j=s,mαj=1
(15)j=s,mβj=1
(16)rs(xj)=i=1Nri(xj)forj=s,m
(17)ps(xj)=i=1Npi(xj)forj=s,m
(18)r(xj)=rs(xj)+rm(xj)forj=s,m
(19)p(xj)=ps(xj)+pm(xj)forj=s,m
(20)αi=αsNumber of suppliers (N)
(21)γi=xiXsxsXs
(22)βi=γi γi

In the presence of a fair strategy, no partner is incentivised to delay the task; therefore, the project is more likely to be completed in time depending on the other risk factors impacting the delay. After devising the fair strategy, it is revealed that the already existing variables pertaining to game theoretic risks remain unchanged and therefore, there is no requirement of updating the BBN model. However, in other situations, the formulation of a policy may necessitate the addition of other nodes to the BBN model. After the introduction of a fair strategy, the game theoretic risks reduce to the minimum level resulting in a low probability of the development time being high.

5. Discussion

This paper provides a theoretical application of the BBNs and Game theory methods with the scope to assessing risks in complex projects within a supply chain network. This simulation, based on existing secondary data regarding the case of Boeing 787, offers an effective example of how to capture the interdependency between risks for a comprehensive risk assessment in complex contexts. The simulation also addresses the different influences that the decision-makers' risk appetite and conflicting incentives may have on the assessment of risks.

The theoretical and managerial implications are relevant. As suggested by several authors (Bevilacqua et al., 2013; Su et al., 2020), managers must achieve a thoughtful understanding of the end-to-end processes, in order to get better performance. To assess and monitor key processes, ISO 9000 and ISO 9001 standards stress the importance of effective measurement systems, based on the adoption of robust audit procedures (Abuazza et al., 2020) and ad hoc quality and risk tools (Castello et al., 2020). The paper offers an insight on how to practically develop a holistic risk analysis approach, in coherence with a process and project management strategy. In doing so, the paper responds to the need to integrate risk management systems and quality management systems, as advocated by recent papers (Samani et al., 2019). According to Mhatre et al. (2017) and Aven (2015), the paper contributes to fill a research gap regarding the lack of studies that assess risks in complex projects, addressing their impacts on supply chain performances. In addition, the paper enriches the studies that apply the interdependence modelling tools in the fields of SCRM and SCQM (Roy et al., 2016; Moeinedini et al., 2018), as also advocated by Huo et al. (2019).

From a managerial perspective, decision-makers can benefit from theoretical simulations and demonstrative case studies, which propose clear examples about how to implement a holistic and comprehensive supply chain risk management process regarding complex projects, also considering the effects of opportunistic behaviours (Qazi et al., 2015; Hosseini and Barker, 2016).

Another key implication for managers, is to offer a tool that could support the implementation of a quantitative “risk based-thinking” tool, as required by ISO 9001 standard and Quality Management System frameworks. In particular, the framework proposed in Figure 1 and the demonstrative case study, based on the secondary data from the Boeing 787 project, allow managers to gain interesting and original insights regarding the development of a strategy of efficiency and timeliness, according to SCRM and SCQM principles (Huo et al., 2019; Das, 2018; Foster, 2008; Colicchia and Strozzi, 2012).

Firstly, managers can reflect on how to consider direct/indirect costs, the network of different suppliers, the loss-sharing and penalty-based contractual conditions, and the overall relationship strategies. In particular, the simulation allows reflecting on the potential actions that suppliers can pursue in the case of a delay, providing three different scenarios, and considering the uncertainty level related to the cost function.

Secondly, thorough the application of a BBN model in the demonstrative case study, managers can find a useful example of the role of careful supplier selection, risk management and bargaining power in defining an effective cost and time strategy. The case allows, in fact, to address multiple factors and highlights that in the context of a fair strategy, where each player is responsible for their own deeds, the project is more likely to be completed in time depending on the other risk factors impacting the delay.

6. Conclusions

This paper has introduced and demonstrated the application of a new process for managing project-driven supply chains that combines two complementary techniques of Game theory and BBNs. The proposed process is capable of capturing the dynamics of interacting risk factors. BBNs provide a useful modelling technique for the quantification of interdependent risk factors, whereas Game theoretic modelling provides an opportunity to model the risks associated with conflicting incentives amongst stakeholders within a supply network. The results of the case study clearly revealed that without mitigating the game theoretic risks, the objective of timely completion of the Boeing 787 project was not accomplished. Furthermore, the lack of management expertise was the major factor contributing to the overall costs of the project. The application of the proposed process to other project-driven supply chains will help decision-makers to visualise a holistic view of interacting interdependent risk factors and identify key risk factors for establishing proactive risk mitigation strategies.

In future, the proposed process may be applied across different industries. Furthermore, empirical research needs to be conducted to investigate the best practices in managing complex interdependencies between project-driven supply chain risks. It will also be important to devise methods for reducing the effort involved in populating such models as when there are limited available data, experts will have to be consulted and the elicitation of the set of conditional probability values will be a real challenge. Methods other than BBNs can be explored to adapt the proposed process and investigate the trade-off between the effort involved in developing the model and the precision of the results.

The proposed process may be extended to involve different stakeholders across a supply chain and contracts can be designed to encourage the active participation of stakeholders within the risk management process. Risk networks may be developed across different industries and compared to establish common patterns in order to develop a generalised risk taxonomy. The cost and benefit analysis may be conducted to help practitioners understand the utility of interdependency-based frameworks. Once the framework gets established in its simplified form of risks and strategies with binary states, these can be modified as continuous variables. The framework may also be extended to capture the dynamic behaviour of risk over time.

Figures

Proposed process for assessing project risks in supply chains

Figure 1

Proposed process for assessing project risks in supply chains

Variation of direct and indirect costs with task and project duration, respectively (source: Qazi et al., 2014)

Figure 2

Variation of direct and indirect costs with task and project duration, respectively (source: Qazi et al., 2014)

A game between two suppliers with uncertainty about the project completion time

Figure 3

A game between two suppliers with uncertainty about the project completion time

A game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other

Figure 4

A game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other

A game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other and the OEM's response

Figure 5

A game between two suppliers with an uncertainty about the cost function of each other and the OEM's response

Cognitive map based on Boeing's perception

Figure 6

Cognitive map based on Boeing's perception

Cognitive map based on real-time risks

Figure 7

Cognitive map based on real-time risks

Summary of BBN results

Management expertiseSupplier selection processOutsourcingFair strategyProbability of time overrun (in percentage)Probability of cost overrun (in percentage)
HighThoroughHighYes3031
HighThoroughHighNo6235
HighThoroughLowYes2426
HighThoroughLowNo5531
HighCasualHighYes3133
HighCasualHighNo6337
HighCasualLowYes2529
HighCasualLowNo5633
LowThoroughHighYes6771
LowThoroughHighNo8375
LowThoroughLowYes4966
LowThoroughLowNo6969
LowCasualHighYes6775
LowCasualHighNo8379
LowCasualLowYes5069
LowCasualLowNo7072

Pay-off functions based on a fair-sharing partnership

Supplier's timelineBoeing's responseBoeing's pay-off
E:xs<XsE:xm<Xmam{r(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)cm(xm)eδ(xm)
K:xm=Xm0
D:xm>Xm{r(xs+Xm)r(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)+sm(xm)eδ(xm)ifxs+xmXs+Xm
{r(xs+Xm)p(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)+sm(xm)eδ(xm)ifxs+xm>Xs+Xm
K:xs=XsE:xm<Xmr(Xs+xm)eδ(xs+xm)cm(xm)eδ(xm)
K:xm=Xm0
D:xm>Xmp(Xs+xm)eδ(xs+xm)+sm(xm)eδ(xm)
D:xs>XsE:xm<Xm{p(xs+Xm)+r(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)cm(xm)eδ(xm)ifxs+xm<Xs+Xm
{p(xs+Xm)p(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)cm(xm)eδ(xm)ifxs+xmXs+Xm
K:xm=Xm0
D:xm>Xmβm{p(xs+xm)}eδ(xs+xm)+s(xm)eδ(xm)
Supplier's timelineSupplier iPay-off of Supplier i
E:xs<XsE:xi<Xsαir(xs+xm)eδ(xs+xm)ci(xi)eδ(xi)ifxs+xmXs+Xm
1N{r(xs+Xm)}eδ(xs+xm)ci(xi)eδ(xi)ifxs+xm>Xs+Xm
K:xs=XsE:xi<Xsci(xi)eδ(xi)
K:xi=Xs0
D:xs>XsE:xi<Xsci(xi)eδ(xi)
K:xi=Xs0
D:xi>Xsβip(xs+Xm)eδ(xs+xm)+s(xi)eδ(xi)ifxs+xm<Xs+Xm
βiβsp(xs+xm)eδ(xs+xm)+s(xi)eδ(xi)ifxs+xmXs+Xmandxm>Xm
βi[{p(xs+Xm)}{p(xs+XM)p(xs+xm)}]eδ(xs+xm)+s(xi)eδ(xi)ifxs+xmXs+XmandxmXm

Note(s): δ is the annual interest rate compounded continuously

References

Abuazza, O.A., Labib, A. and Savage, B.M. (2020), “Development of an auditing framework by integrating ISO 9001 principles within auditing”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 37, pp. 328-353.

Ackermann, F., Eden, C., Williams, T. and Howick, S. (2006), “Systemic risk assessment: a case study”, Journal of the Operational Research Society, Vol. 58, pp. 39-51, doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jors.2602105.

Ackermann, F., Howick, S., Quigley, J., Walls, L. and Houghton, T. (2014), “Systemic risk elicitation: using causal maps to engage stakeholders and build a comprehensive view of risks”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 238, pp. 290-299, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2014.03.035.

Aloini, D., Dulmin, R., Mininno, V. and Ponticelli, S. (2012), “Supply chain management: a review of implementation risks in the construction industry”, Business Process Management Journal, Vol. 18, pp. 735-761, doi: 10.1108/14637151211270135.

Aven, T. (2015), “Risk assessment and risk management: review of recent advances on their foundation”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 253, pp. 1-13, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2015.12.023.

Badurdeen, F., Shuaib, M., Wijekoon, K., Brown, A., Faulkner, W., Amundson, J., Jawahir, I.S., Goldsby, T.J., Iyengar, D. and Boden, B. (2014), “Quantitative modeling and analysis of supply chain risks using bayesian theory”, Journal of Manufacturing Technology Management, Vol. 25, pp. 631-654, doi: 10.1108/JMTM-10-2012-0097.

Bevilacqua, M., Ciarapica, F.E., Giacchetta, G. and Marchetti, B. (2013), “An empirical study of ISO 9000 on the supply chain of a company leader in the heating sector”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 30, pp. 897-916.

Boateng, P., Chen, Z. and Ogunlana, S.O. (2015), “An analytical network process model for risks prioritisation in megaprojects”, International Journal of Project Management, Vol. 33, pp. 1795-1811, doi: 10.1016/j.ijproman.2015.08.007.

Castello, J., De Castro, R. and Marimon, F. (2020), “Use of quality tools and techniques and their integration into ISO 9001”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 37, pp. 68-89.

Chapman, C. and Ward, S. (2004), “Why risk efficiency is a key aspect of best practice projects”, International Journal of Project Management, Vol. 22, pp. 619-632.

Christopher, M. and Peck, H. (2004), “Building the resilient supply chain”, International Journal of Logistics Management, Vol. 15, pp. 1-14, doi: 10.1108/09574090410700275.

Colicchia, C. and Strozzi, F. (2012), “Supply chain risk management: a new methodology for a systematic literature review”, Supply Chain Management: An International Journal, Vol. 17, pp. 403-418, doi: 10.1108/13598541211246558.

Das, K. (2018), “Integrating resilience in a supply chain planning model”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 35, pp. 570-595.

Denning, S. (2013a), “Boeing's offshoring woes: seven lessons every ceo must learn”, Strategy and Leadership, Vol. 41, pp. 29-35, doi: 10.1108/10878571311323190.

Denning, S. (2013b), “What went wrong at boeing”, Strategy and Leadership, Vol. 41, pp. 36-41, doi: 10.1108/10878571311323208.

Doloi, H., Sawhney, A., Iyer, K. and Rentala, S. (2012), “Analysing factors affecting delays in indian construction projects”, International Journal of Project Management, Vol. 30, pp. 479-489.

Fang, C., Marle, F., Zio, E. and Bocquet, J.-C. (2012), Network theory-based analysis of risk interactions in large engineering projects, Reliability Engineering and System Safety, Vol. 106, pp. 1-10, doi: 10.1016/j.ress.2012.04.005.

Foster, S.T., Jr (2008), “Towards an understanding of supply chain quality management”, Journal of Operations Management, Vol. 26, pp. 461-467.

Garvey, M.D., Carnovale, S. and Yeniyurt, S. (2015), “An analytical framework for supply network risk propagation: a bayesian network approach”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 243, pp. 618-627, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2014.10.034.

Gaudenzi, B. and Borghesi, A. (2006), “Managing risks in the supply chain using the ahp method”, International Journal of Logistics Management, Vol. 17, pp. 114-136, doi: 10.1108/09574090610663464.

Ghadge, A., Dani, S. and Kalawsky, R. (2012), “Supply chain risk management: present and future scope”, International Journal of Logistics Management, Vol. 23, pp. 313-339, doi: 10.1108/09574091211289200.

Greising, D. and Johnsson, J. (2007), “Behind Boeing's 787 delays”, Chicago Tribune, Vol. 10, pp. 1-7.

Haleem, A., Sushil Qadri, M.A. and Kumar, S. (2012), “Analysis of critical success factors of world-class manufacturing practices: an application of interpretative structural modelling and interpretative ranking process”, Production Planning and Control, Vol. 23, pp. 722-734.

Hosseini, S. and Barker, K. (2016), “A bayesian network model for resilience-based supplier selection”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 180, pp. 68-87.

Huo, B., Ye, Y., Zhao, X. and Zhu, K. (2019), “Supply chain quality integration: a taxonomy perspective”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 207, pp. 236-246.

Jensen, F.V. and Nielsen, T.D. (2007), Bayesian Networks and Decision Graphs, Springer-Verlag, New York.

Kardes, I., Ozturk, A., Cavusgil, S.T. and Cavusgil, E. (2013), “Managing global megaprojects: complexity and risk management”, International Business Review, Vol. 22, pp. 905-917, doi: 10.1016/j.ibusrev.2013.01.003.

Khan, O., Christopher, M. and Burnes, B. (2008), “The impact of product design on supply chain risk: a case study”, International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, Vol. 38, pp. 412-432, doi: 10.1108/09600030810882834.

Kjaerulff, U.B. and Anders, L.M. (2008), Bayesian Networks and Influence Diagrams: A Guide to Construction and Analysis, Springer-Verlag, New York.

Knemeyer, A.M., Zinn, W. and Eroglu, C. (2009), “Proactive planning for catastrophic events in supply chains”, Journal of Operations Management, Vol. 27, pp. 141-153, doi: 10.1016/j.jom.2008.06.002.

Lee, C.K.M., Yeung, Y.C. and Hong, Z. (2012), “An integrated framework for outsourcing risk management”, Industrial Management and Data Systems, Vol. 112, pp. 541-558, doi: 10.1108/02635571211225477.

Lin, Y. and Zhou, L. (2011), “The impacts of product design changes on supply chain risk: a case study”, International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, Vol. 41, pp. 162-186, doi: 10.1108/09600031111118549.

Lockamy, A. (2014), “Assessing disaster risks in supply chains”, Industrial Management and Data Systems, Vol. 114, pp. 755-777, doi: 10.1108/IMDS-11-2013-0477.

Lutz, H., Vang, D.O. and Raffield, W.D. (2012), “Using game theory to predict supply chain cooperation”, Performance Improvement, Vol. 51, pp. 19-23, doi: 10.1002/pfi.21251.

Mhatre, T.N., Thakkar, J. and Maiti, J. (2017), “Modelling critical risk factors for indian construction project using interpretive ranking process (irp) and system dynamics (sd)”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 34, pp. 1451-1473.

Moeinedini, M., Raissi, S. and Khalili-Damghani, K. (2018), “A fuzzy fault tree analysis based risk assessment approach for enterprise resource planning projects: a case study in an iranian foodservice distributor”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 35, pp. 1115-1141.

Nepal, B. and Yadav, O.P. (2015), “Bayesian belief network-based framework for sourcing risk analysis during supplier selection”, International Journal of Production Research, Vol. 53, pp. 6114-6135, doi: 10.1080/00207543.2015.1027011.

Nieto-Morote, A. and Ruz-Vila, F. (2011), “A fuzzy approach to construction project risk assessment”, International Journal of Project Management, Vol. 29, pp. 220-231, doi 10.1016/j.ijproman.2010.02.002.

Osborne, M. (2003), An Introduction to Game Theory, Oxford University Press, Incorporated.

Pfohl, H.-C., Gallus, P. and Thomas, D. (2011), “Interpretive structural modeling of supply chain risks”, International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, Vol. 41, pp. 839-859, doi: 10.1108/09600031111175816.

Qazi, A., Quigley, J. and Dickson, A. (2014), “A novel framework for quantification of supply chain risks”, in 4th Student Conference on Operational Research.

Qazi, A., Quigley, J. and Dickson, A. (2015), “Supply chain risk management: systematic literature review and a conceptual framework for capturing interdependencies between risks”, in 5th International Conference on Industrial Engineering and Operations Management, pp. 1-13, doi: 10.1109/IEOM.2015.7093701.

Qazi, A., Quigley, J., Dickson, A. and Kirytopoulos, K. (2016), “Project complexity and risk management (procrim): towards modelling project complexity driven risk paths in construction projects”, International Journal of Project Management, Vol. 34, pp. 1183-1198, doi: 10.1016/j.ijproman.2016.05.008.

Qazi, A., Dickson, A., Quigley, J. and Gaudenzi, B. (2018), “Supply chain risk network management: a bayesian belief network and expected utility based approach for managing supply chain risks”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 196, pp. 24-42.

Roy, S.K., Sarkar, A. and Mahanty, B. (2016), “Fuzzy risk assessment for electro-optical target tracker”, International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, Vol. 33, pp. 830-851.

Samani, M., Ismail, N., Leman, Z. and Zulkifli, N. (2019), “Development of a conceptual model for risk-based quality management system”, Total Quality Management and Business Excellence, Vol. 30, pp. 483-498.

Sigurdsson, J.H., Walls, L.A. and Quigley, J.L. (2001), “Bayesian belief nets for managing expert judgement and modelling reliability”, Quality and Reliability Engineering International, Vol. 17, pp. 181-190, doi: 10.1002/qre.410.

Sinha, P.R., Whitman, L.E. and Malzahn, D. (2004), “Methodology to mitigate supplier risk in an aerospace supply chain”, Supply Chain Management: An International Journal, Vol. 9, pp. 154-168, doi: 10.1108/13598540410527051.

Son, J.Y. and Orchard, R.K. (2013), “Effectiveness of policies for mitigating supply disruptions”, International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, Vol. 43, pp. 684-706, doi: 10.1108/IJPDLM-04-2012-0109.

Squire, B. (2010), “Managing supply chain risks: understanding the impact of network characteristics”, in Managing Risk in Virtual Enterprise Networks: Implementing Supply Chain Principles Book Section Hershey, IGI Global, Hershey, pp. 28-48, doi: 10.4018/978-1-61520-607-0.ch002.

Su, H.-C., Kao, T.-W. and Linderman, K. (2020), “Where in the supply chain network does ISO 9001 improve firm productivity?”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 283, pp. 530-540.

Tang, O. and Nurmaya Musa, S. (2011), “Identifying risk issues and research advancements in supply chain risk management”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 133, pp. 25-34, doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2010.06.013.

Tang, C.S., Zimmerman, J.D. and Nelson, J.I. (2009), “Managing new product development and supply chain risks: the Boeing 787 case”, Supply Chain Forum: An International Journal, Vol. 10, pp. 74-86.

Wagner, S.M. and Bode, C. (2008), “An emperical examination of supply chain performance along several dimensions of risk”, Journal of Business Logistics, Vol. 29, pp. 307-325, doi: 10.1002/j.2158-1592.2008.tb00081.x.

Wagner, S.M. and Neshat, N. (2010), “Assessing the vulnerability of supply chains using graph theory”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 126, pp. 121-129, doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2009.10.007.

Wakolbinger, T. and Cruz, J.M. (2010), “Supply chain disruption risk management through strategic information acquisition and sharing and risk-sharing contracts”, International Journal of Production Research, Vol. 49, pp. 4063-4084, doi: 10.1080/00207543.2010.501550.

Williams, T. (2005), “Assessing and moving on from the dominant project management discourse in the light of project overruns”, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, Vol. 52, pp. 497-508, doi: 10.1109/TEM.2005.856572.

Xin, X. and Zhao, Y. (2013), “Incentives and coordination in project driven supply chains”, Working Paper, Rutgers Business School, Newark and New Brunswick, NJ.

Zhao, Y. (2013), “Why 787 slips were inevitable?”, Working Paper, Rutgers Business School, Newark and New Brunswick, NJ.

Zhao, R., Neighbour, G., Han, J., McGuire, M. and Deutz, P. (2012), “Using game theory to describe strategy selection for environmental risk and carbon emissions reduction in the green supply chain”, Journal of Loss Prevention in the Process Industries, Vol. 25, pp. 927-936, doi: 10.1016/j.jlp.2012.05.004.

Zhao, L., Huo, B., Sun, L. and Zhao, X. (2013), “The impact of supply chain risk on supply chain integration and company performance: a global investigation”, Supply Chain Management: An International Journal, Vol. 18, pp. 115-131, doi: 10.1108/13598541311318773.

Corresponding author

Barbara Gaudenzi and can be contacted at: barbara.gaudenzi@univr.it

Related articles