An analysis of the normative parameters of reward and risk in Islamic finance

Mohamed Benaicha (International Islamic University Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia)

ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance

ISSN: 2289-4365

Article publication date: 29 September 2020

Issue publication date: 21 December 2020

2139

Abstract

Purpose

This study aims to define the parameters of the reward-risk principle in Islamic finance as established in the literature and discuss propositions that are presented on how such a principle is to be applied to Islamic banking products.

Design/methodology/approach

A descriptive approach is used to explore the normative parameters and criticisms of the application of reward-risk in Islamic finance.

Findings

The study finds that the principle of reward-risk is embodied in the multi-component concept of ʿiwaḍ (counter value) which must be evident in market transactions that involve commercial exchanges. The components include risk, costs, effort, value-adding and capital, all of which apply uniquely to different contractual forms of financing.

Research limitations/implications

The study uses academic literature and industry documents along with modest contact with prominent practitioners who provided general feedback on prevalent Islamic finance industry practices.

Practical implications

This study exposits the variety of approaches in applying the reward-risk principle and sheds light on the primary elements of the principle which will facilitate its greater consideration by the Islamic finance industry.

Originality/value

This study is a meaningful attempt at conveniently summing up and applying the parameters that are considered when discussing the scope of the reward-risk principle in Islamic finance.

Keywords

Citation

Benaicha, M. (2020), "An analysis of the normative parameters of reward and risk in Islamic finance", ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 303-323. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJIF-07-2019-0100

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2020, Mohamed Benaicha.

License

Published in ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


Introduction

Islamic finance (IF) is practiced today by financial intermediaries, which circulate funds from providers to users of funds. Islamic financial institutions (IFIs) use the contracts developed in fiqh (Islamic jurisprudence) literature to devise products that can be used to circulate funds in a way that is Sharīʿah compliant (in abidance by Islamic law). Some examples of these contracts are the typical sale contract, which entails the transfer of ownership and the lease contract, which gives another party the right to benefit from the leased asset. Besides these contracts, there are principles that must be observed. They include the prohibition of gharar (extreme uncertainty); the prohibition of maysir (gambling-like speculative activities); and the prohibition of ribā (usury), which takes different forms such as interest on a loan. Another of these principles is matching reward with risk. In other words, the benefits that accrue to each party in a transaction must also reflect a level of risk that is assumed by that party. This principle is referred to as “reward-risk” in this study.

The words “reward” and “risk” are close interpretations of what the Prophet (peace be upon him) said and what jurists understood from ḥadīths (sayings of the Prophet) that pertain to such matters. These include the terms used in ḥadīth:

«اَلْخَرَاجُ بِالضَّمَانِ».

“Reward (kharāj) goes with liability (ḍamān)” (al-Tirmidhī, 1975, ḥadīth no. 1286).

Liability entails risk while the reward is understood to mean income. Each term, reward and risk, will be defined individually later. Until recently, IF textbooks such as that by Abojeib et al. (2018) have highlighted the profit-and-loss sharing (PLS) principle as the distinguishing feature between Islamic and conventional arrangements. This principle dictates that profit and capital loss in a partnership be shared among the partners. PLS is one embodiment of the reward-risk principle and is a testament to its importance, which necessitates revisiting the juristic interpretations of ḥadīth texts that institute this principle.

In discussing risk, conventional economists do not agree on one definition and have instead advanced various definitions of risk, some of which have more practical implications than others. According to Holton (2004), both subjective and objective theories of probabilities have been advanced in defining probability and risk. For example, Knight defines risk as an objective probability in that it is measurable yet one is ignorant of it Holton (2004). Keynes requires that two propositions of probability be presented to determine risk, notably an objectivist and a logical proposition, as two individuals would arrive at the same risk calculation if presented with the same propositions of probability (Holton, 2004). After analyzing several ideas on risk by prominent economists, Holton (2004) goes on to identify two important elements of risk, namely, exposure and uncertainty. IF experts have also attempted to define risk. For example, al-Suwailem (2006, p. 56) defines it as “the probability of loss.” From this definition, it is clear that risk is undesirable. Askari et al. (2012, p. 69) define it as the “possible occurrence of an event that leads to a loss.” They further add that such risk is reduced by transferring it or sharing it. This further distinguishes it from gharar, which refers to taking an excessive amount of risk (al-Suwailem, 2006; Askari et al., 2012).

The concept of risk in IF will be elaborated later. Regarding the concept of kharāj (reward) in the previously mentioned ḥadīth (al-Tirmidhī, 1975, ḥadīth no. 1286), it refers specifically to an incident where a man purchased a hired worker (servant) but then returned him to the seller after discovering a flaw in him that had not been disclosed at the time of purchase. The owner complained to the Prophet (peace be upon him) that the buyer had used the servant’s labor during that period but had not compensated the original owner for it. The Prophet (peace be upon him) ruled that the buyer was not required to pay any compensation because he was liable for the servant during the period he had used his labor. In light of this context, kharāj refers to any dakhl (income) or ghullah (usufruct) and is specifically tied to the ownership from which such income is derived (al-Khaṭṭābī, 1932).

Some IF literature defines kharāj as all sorts of income that are distributed to transactors (Awidha, 2010). Some specific examples include the sale price and profit in a sale contract, the rental payment in a lease contract, the profit in partnership-based contracts such as muḍārabah (profit-sharing) and mushārakah (profit-and-loss sharing) and fees in agency contracts. What constitutes kharāj is not a subject of unanimity and has largely been left undefined in fiqh and IF literature. This is, perhaps, owing to the evolving nature of Islamic financial arrangements. In an Islamic financial lease product today, for example, the Islamic bank (IB) would earn an income that is made up of the financing amount and profit, which are paid in rental installments. Attempting to fix the types of kharāj may work to defeat the purpose of the malleability of Sharīʿah (Islamic law) and its principles of muʿāmalāt (transactions).

Another important introductory concept related to reward-risk is ʿiwaḍ, which is best translated as fair counter-value or compensation. Further developed by some IF experts, ʿiwaḍ traces its roots to a concept in the Ḥanafī School, as elaborated by the jurist al-Kāsānī (1986), of legitimate return on invested equity capital. It is necessary to expound on the components of ʿiwaḍ as they represent one view of how reward-risk in IF should take form. Reward-risk parameters will be discussed and applied to the fiqh contracts used today for purposes of clarification. The categories of sale, lease and partnership contracts will be the primary focus. Other categories such as qarḍ (loan) and wakālah (agency) are out of the scope of this study although they are not excluded from the implications of the reward-risk principle.

This study aims to define the parameters of the reward-risk principle in IF literature and how such a principle is to be applied to Islamic banking products. The results do not represent the researcher’s opinion but are simply the product of inductive analysis. The study uses academic and industry literature with some feedback from practitioners on the actual practice for purposes of an objective demonstration of the practice. Furthermore, the study alludes to the variety of approaches in applying the reward-risk principle and sheds light on the parameters of the principle in hopes of increasing awareness of this theory, which is discussed but has not yet taken full shape. This study expects to present a unique and arguably unprecedented attempt at comprehensively summing up and applying the parameters of the reward-risk principle in their current form.

The study first conducts a review of the literature on the reward-risk principle and its application in the different fiqh contracts, both in their traditional fiqh and modern IF manifestations. Criticisms of the modern IB financing practice are also abbreviated therein. The study then presents the researcher’s findings, outlining the proposed parameters of the reward-risk principle and discussing the finer elements that relate to each parameter of the principle. The last section summarizes the findings and proposes recommendations for future research.

Reward and risk parameters in the Islamic finance literature

The principle of reward-risk stems from the ḥadīth of al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān (reward is justified through liability) (al-Tirmidhī, 1975, ḥadīth no. 1286). This liability has been interpreted to mean liability for risk/loss or liability for sound disposition of the asset such that if the asset in a sale contract is safely disposed of by the seller to the buyer, the former deserves the income from the transaction (Mahmud, 2019). The context of the ḥadīth has already been discussed. Another narration conveying a similar meaning states that the Prophet (peace be upon him) prohibited that one earns a profit from something for which he bears no liability (Mālik, 1985, ḥadīth no. 251).

IF thought has not diverged much from the established classical fiqh stance toward the reward-risk principle. Al-Ṣadr (1981) viewed reward being matched with risk in the likes of muḍārabah and mushārakah in the form of sharing of profits and assuming risk. That is why an ajīr (fixed-wage hired labor) receives limited but guaranteed wages whereas a muḍarīb (managerial labor) is not guaranteed a return but stands to benefit a lot more from a successful venture than an ajīr. That is because the muḍarīb shares the profits of the muḍārabah (which refers to a venture involving two parties, a financier and a managerial laborer). Choudhury (1986) confirms that the dominant form of financing in Islamic countries was based on the principle of profit-and-risk sharing. Kahf and Khan (1992) confirm that al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān is an important axiom of IF. Like them, Chapra (1992) reiterates the same idea under the subtopic of equitable distribution and lists several parameters of the reward-risk principle. Equitable distribution through the reward-risk application would prevent wealth from being concentrated in the hands of a few and, in turn, achieve the ideals of the revelation (Iqbal, 1997, 1999). This is in reference to the Qurʾānic verse: “[…] so that it (wealth) may not circulate only among the rich among you” (59:7). Put simply, the reward-risk principle ensures that, regardless of the contractual methods used, commercial exchanges achieve an equitable balance of income and risk. In the context of IF today, IBs earn income from financing and they bear the risk of that financing.

The focus of Islamic economics experts when discussing reward-risk is the domain of wealth distribution and Sharīʿah injunctions that pertain to it. Distribution refers to the division of products among participating factors such as land, labor and so forth (Abojeib et al., 2018). The primary theme in distribution that ties it to IF is equitability. Hence, the primary concern in Islamic economics is in regulating the distribution and ensuring it is equitable, with the Qurʾān giving more attention to it than to production. This is relevant to the study at hand, as IF is a subset of the larger Islamic economic system. In an attempt to achieve the ideals of Islamic economics, IF experts and practitioners have developed contractual methods to try to achieve equity, specifically through the concept of ʿiwaḍ proposed by some.

Rosly (2001) and Abdullah (2015, 2016) are prominent exponents of the concept of ʿiwaḍ, which for them stands at the center of the IF normative theory of profits. Hence, if income is earned by transacting parties, the requirements of ʿiwaḍ must be properly observed for the financing to be equitable. ʿIwaḍ is further composed of ghurm (risk), ribḥ (earnings), ʿamal (effort) as an addition of value and ḍamān. In classical fiqh literature, ʿiwaḍ is a prevalent theme in equity-based financing (al-Kāsānī, 1986). Ribā is prohibited because the lender is entitled to a guaranteed return above the principal and the guaranteed principal sum in full. This negates any risk being taken for the return earned. The mentioned components of ʿiwaḍ have been generalized to include some sale-based arrangements. The basis for those who do this is that the Qurʾān distinguishes between an invalid ribawī (usurious) sale and a valid sale (Qurʾān, 2:275) chiefly on the basis of the risk involved in the latter. A slightly different set of elements comprise ʿiwaḍ in partnerships, namely, māl (capital), ʿamal and ḍamān, with profit-sharing being the goal of partnerships. The rabb al-māl (capital provider) advances capital to the muḍārib (manager) who manages it. The rabb al-māl bears the risk of loss associated with the investment of the capital (Rosly, 2001).

The specific elements of transactional dealings to which the reward-risk principle applies (within the context of the contracts chosen in this study) include, namely, asset price for sale contracts, rental rates in lease contracts and profit rates in partnerships which are determined by the profitability of the ventures. Similarly, the risk pertains to ownership risk in sale/lease contracts and loss of capital/effort in partnership contracts.

In sale contracts, market price risk may affect profit or loss; the reward is the income from reselling the asset, but an asset may prove unsaleable due to lack of demand (Awidha, 2010). These are expressed as the benefits and risks of ownership (Kahf and Khan, 1992; Hussain et al., 2016), where the possibility of profiting from a resale is met with the risk of not being able to resell the asset or reselling it at a loss or even having the asset destroyed. This distinguishes sale from ribā in that the latter is a risk-free “profit” (return) whereas the former is profit associated with ownership and market risk.

In leases, the rewards and risks take different forms, the most important of which are the ability to lease the assets at a good lease rate (reward) and the risk of wear and tear or of the destruction of leased assets due to force majeure (overwhelming circumstances) (Hussain et al., 2016). The lease payments earned are due to the ownership risk borne by the lessor (Rosly, 2001). Ijārah (lease) is basically a sale contract, but it is done on a temporary basis and for a fraction of the price (Ibn Qudāmah, 1968; al-Ashqar, 1998; Kamali, 2007). For this reason, future lease rates should, in principle, not be fixed but rather be subjected to market conditions. However, due to the gharar (uncertainty) element contained in such a stipulation, Sharīʿah texts require that lease rates be defined in value (Ibn Qudāmah, 1968); Al-Zuḥaily, 1984 Setting a floating lease benchmark as the basis for lease rate determination is acceptable, as the value of the index is defined at any given point in time, which eliminates gharar and reflects real sector lease rates (Hussain et al., 2016). Alternatively, Kahf (2020a) compares the fixed-wage of an ajīr (who leases his labor) with the varying profits of a muḍārib in that both do virtually the same things but differ in risk appetite. The Sharīʿah approves of both approaches of the income distribution. Reward-risk in lease contracts can take the form of the accrual of any benefits – other than those stipulated for the lessee – from the leased asset to the original owner (lessor). This is because it is a transfer of temporary right to usufruct and not the transfer of ownership; ownership remains with the lessor, which necessitates bearing the risk of loss of the leased asset (Shariff and Rahman, 2003). An implication of this, for example, is that the destruction of the asset due to the lessee’s negligence does not affect the lessor’s entitlement to rental payments (Ibn Qudāmah, 1968).

In muḍārabah partnerships, the profit is the return on equity while the risk relates to the capital loss of the rabb al-māl and the efforts of the muḍārib. In mushārakah, the reward is the partners’ profit on capital and the risk is the partners’ potential loss of capital (Ibn Qudāmah, 1968; Hamoud, 1982; Khan, 1987; al-Sālūs, 1995; Ibn ʿAbd al-Barr, 2000; Rosly, 2001; Ibn Rushd, 2004; Awidha, 2010; Askari et al., 2012). In parallel (two-tier) muḍārabah, the IB acts as a muḍārib initially receiving funds from depositors (as rabb al-māl) and then invests the capital into other projects/ventures as a new rabb al-māl, a novelty in contemporary IF which is alien to the classical fiqh literature (Kahf and Khan, 1992). It has, however, caused controversy over the method of application of reward-risk: who bears the risk of capital loss? Hamoud (1982), for example, allows guarantees by the IB because the IB itself is entitled to a profit (as rabb al-māl in the second tier of the muḍārabah) and so, must guarantee the capital. That capital, in turn, is the entitlement of the initial rabb al-māl (the depositors). This has been refuted by some scholars like Awidha (2010), who have discussed Hamoud’s proposition and pointed out its faults. On the same grounds, al-Ṣadr (1981) views that the initial muḍārib (IB) is not entitled to a share of the profits unless there is a real effort on its behalf in managing the funds of the rabb al-māl (depositors).

An identifiable gap in the literature exists with regard to a concise analysis and summary of the parameters of reward-risk in light of modern Islamic financial intermediation. This paper seeks to address that gap.

Methodology

This study adopts a descriptive approach to explain the concept and application of reward-risk to IB financing products. An inductive analysis of the different opinions presented by IF experts and researchers form the basis for discussing and defining the currently established normative parameters of reward-risk. Critical observations regarding prominent Malaysian IB financing products, through document analysis and practitioners’ input and their reward-risk features, are also made.

Defining the parameters of reward-risk

The results reveal that market and ownership risk, transactional costs, effort or added value and risk of capital loss are all important parameters that define the reward-risk principle. Each parameter will be discussed individually.

Risk (ghurm)

Having defined risk earlier, it is necessary to systematically present it as a parameter of the reward-risk principle. In the medieval context during which fiqh developed, merchant-style financial dealings, rather than financial intermediation, were the norm. This meant that a trader bought goods which he sold for profit. Inherent in this process is the exposure to loss of the asset and the risk of selling it at a loss in the market. The well-established near-consensus in IF discourse is that the risk referred to here is based on the principle of istimrāriyyat al-milk (ownership risk) (Kahf and Khan, 1992; Awidha, 2010; Dusuki, 2016). According to earlier and later Islamic economists, owning an asset or share capital in a venture means that, to profit, one must resell it or use it to produce goods/services for sale, which naturally exposes one to market risk; this, in turn, justifies fair return: ʿiwaḍ (al-Ṣadr, 1981; Kahf, 2002; Abdullah, 2015, 2016). By inference, ownership risk and market risk are inextricable risks in the context of the reward-risk principle. The following discussion sheds light on these two forms of risk.

Market risk refers to the “change in the financial position due to changes in the value of underlying components on which that position depends” (Muhammad et al., 2015, p. 308) or the “risk associated with a change in the market value of held assets” (El-Hawary et al., 2007, p. 797). The free market, through its demand and supply mechanism, is the fair determinant for prices which, by logic, are important determinants of returns and profits (al-Ṣadr, 1981; Awidha, 2010; Abojeib et al., 2018). The possession of an asset, whether physical or financial, entails that benefiting from it will require using it. This may expose it to the possibility of damage or loss, such as when the asset is leased. When individual wishes to dispose of the asset, they will likely sell it at the prevailing market price. This illustrates the risk of owning any asset and of wishing to either earn from it by using it for production or leasing it or selling it off. The questions that then arise are: how does ownership risk and market risk uniquely affect the different contractual forms? Furthermore, why are not other risks as relevant in discussing reward-risk? Finally, how do costs of ownership relate to risk?

Ownership risk and market risk are normative forms of risk pertaining to the reward-risk principle. This means that these two risks seem to embody the ideal of risk-taking to justify a return. This is clarified through a demonstration of their application to IB financing products, although the reward-risk application has theoretically been extended to a variety of other fiqh contracts. The primary contractual categories using IB financing products are sale, lease and partnership contracts. Reward-risk applies slightly differently to each, but the forms of risk that apply are either one or both of ownership and market risks. The third type, capital loss risk, is discussed under the section of māl due to its unique nature.

In bayʿ (sale) structures, market price affects the resale value of the assets (Rosly, 2001). In the case of IF today, the resale of an asset-based on a sale contract, be it bayʿ bi thaman ājil (BBA – deferred payment sale) or murābaḥah (mark-up sale) or salam (forward commodity sale), entails market risk (Khan, 1994). The BBA and murābaḥah contracts are mark-up modes which were, and still are, used excessively in Islamic banking and finance (Khan, 1994; Suzuki and Miah, 2018) and entail the sale of an asset already in the possession of the seller. Hence, the sale price, whatever it is, can only be determined after the buyer agrees to buy the asset, in turn, exposing the seller to market risk (Rosly, 2001). Alternately, the seller may not find a buyer for a period in which market values of the asset change and when a buyer comes along, the agreed purchase price may be different from the cost of the asset (either less or more, entailing a loss or profit). The analogy drawn here is that the IB is the seller and the customer is the buyer. The market risk here should be duly borne by the IB.

Financial engineering has allowed for the development of the likes of the murābaḥah to the purchase orderer (MPO) which essentially eliminates any market risk in that the IB will only purchase the asset to resell it at a higher value if the buyer undertakes, in a binding manner (legally enforceable), to purchase the asset from the IB (Awidha, 2010). Murābaḥah initially did not entail risk-free profit in fiqh discourse (Abdullah, 2016). Similarly, ʿīnah (deferred payment sale followed by a spot payment repurchase of the same asset) mitigates market risks (Abdullah, 2015). By inference, tawarruq (like ʿīnah but includes a third party) does so and the two sale transactions are affected simultaneously which leaves no room for exposure to market forces (Khan, 2009; Dusuki, 2010). While such financially-engineered arrangements do mitigate market risk, they do not necessarily do so in regard to ownership risk, as the financier bears the ownership risk in mark-up modes, up and until the asset is sold to the customer (Hamoud, 1982; Khan, 1994; Kahf, 2006). Ownership risk will be discussed shortly. Figure 1 illustrates the structures of an MPO, al-ijārah thumma al-bayʿ (AITAB) and mushārakah mutanāqiṣah partnership (MMP).

In lease-based arrangements, such as property, equipment and vehicle finance, the value of the lease is determined by the cumulative rental rate (sum of all rental payments). Hence, a lease asset’s usefulness to the lessor is subject to the prevailing lease prices in the market. Alternately, prospective lessees vie in bargaining for below-market rental rates subjecting the lessor to market price risk, and all the while the lessor is exposed to ownership risk. In more complex lease-based arrangements such as the Islamic financial lease like AITAB (an Islamic financial lease used in Malaysia as detailed in Figure 1), market risk is technically irrelevant. The claim is that the lessor (IB) should normally be exposed to prevailing market rental rates. The claim further purports that the IB’s return on the leased asset should be – all else equal – positively influenced by higher rental rates. Instead, the IB would not necessarily fix the rates but guarantee itself a certain income so as to recuperate the purchase costs of the leased asset plus the desired profit throughout the lease; or through the lease and subsequent sale of the asset. The issue of variable rental rates being subject to market rates is arguable, but what is not arguable is the fact that market risk becomes almost irrelevant in an AITAB. Thus, it is observed that the mitigation of market risk, which is achieved through the guise of credit guarantee (through a wa‘d or undertaking that requires all rental payments be made by the lessee) and long lock-in periods, is what renders the Islamic financial lease incoherent with the reward-risk principle. Figure 1 also illustrates the reward-risk elements of an AITAB.

Partnership-based arrangements, mainly muḍārabah and mushārakah, entail the sharing of profits and losses. The IB advances capital to the customer, be it to finance an asset or a venture. Jurists have established that the profits are the returns on capital invested while the losses include losses on capital invested, and of effort and managerial labor by the partners. In muḍārabah, capital is given by the IB (rabb al-māl) to the customer (muḍārib) as venture finance. In mushārakah, the IB and customer share in the venture by both contributing capital into it or in owning an asset. In both cases, the basic rule is that the IB and customer share the profits. If a capital loss results, it is borne solely by the IB in the muḍārabah, whereas it is shared between the IB and customer in the mushārakah. As partnership contracts pertain to the parameter of māl (capital), their unique nature will be further elaborated when discussing the māl parameter.

Al-Ṣadr (1981) stipulated that a muḍārib (A) cannot invest the capital vested to it by the rabb al-māl with another muḍārib (B) by an arrangement in which no effort or labor is exerted. This is because the first muḍārib (A) would earn a profit that is not matched with the risk of loss of effort as no effort was put forth, to begin with. What is relevant here is that the risk of loss of capital entitles the rabb al-māl to a return while the risk of wasted efforts or labor is what entitles the muḍārib to a share in the profits. A wakīl (agent) may be delegated instead of a muḍārib, in which case the former receives an ujrah (fee) for its efforts while the muwakkil (principal) still bears the full risk of losing its capital and is entitled to whatever remains after the agent receives its fees. This is a form of investment called wakālah finance, which is not practiced as a direct financing product but merely used as a supplementary contract in IB financing facilities.

More complex partnership structures include the MMP offered by IBs for asset financing. Market risk is not so relevant in the MMP structure, as one of the partners – the one providing the majority of the financing – ensures that it will recuperate the full costs of the financed asset along with desired profits from the initial down payment and fixed or floating rental rates. This is done through the guise of credit guarantee mechanisms such as waʿd, which requires the purchase of all of the IB’s shares in the asset by the customer. This renders market risk completely irrelevant as the value of the financing for the financier does not change with changing asset values or market rental rates. This is why a Sharīʿah committee member of a Malaysian-owned IB cited by Zabri and Mohammed (2018) views MMP in practice as more of a sale-based arrangement with fixed returns. The same individual states that the MMP may also have an economic output similar to that of an AITAB, raising questions as to the embodiment of PLS in MMP products. Figure 1 further illustrates this.

Ownership risk should apply differently to the different contractual categories discussed, as they are fundamentally different. Sale contracts entail the sale of an asset already in the possession of the seller while lease contracts entail the rental of an asset that may or may not be in the possession of the lessor. Partnerships may have capital in the form of money, in which case ownership risk is not directly relevant. It is then observed that ownership risk is what eventually exposes the asset owner to market risk. Without ownership risk, the asset owner cannot bear market risk, as, according to the Prophetic narration, one is not allowed to sell that which he does not own (al-Tirmidhī, 1975, ḥadīth no. 1232). This is relevant, as more complex forms of the aforementioned arrangements like the MPO claim to feature ownership risk but mitigate all market risk, which raises doubts about the structuring of such forms of financing and their consideration for reward-risk. The reader shall be reminded here that to make sure that the proceeds of the financing are distributed equitably, risk must match reward. It has also been shown that the AITAB and MMP products do not regard market risk at all, meaning that the lessor and the partner have ownership yet are exposed to no market risk.

In conclusion, ghurm is risk and can take various forms, from market or ownership risk to loss of expended effort. Modern IB financing products have not properly observed these risks. The reason must be either that the proposed parameters of reward-risk are unrealistic or rigid or that the practice has intentionally ignored their consideration. However, there are other risks that are inherent to exchange or market transactions but which are not considered to fall within the scope of the reward-risk principle, as will follow.

Other risks

The main premise for the lack of extensive concern with other risks when dealing with the reward-risk parameters is that such risks may be permissibly or forcefully mitigated (as part and parcel of achieving justice), such as credit risk and certain fiduciary risk, respectively. Alternately, these other risks may be inherent in the transaction and so cannot possibly be eliminated fully, such as business risk. Or it may be that such risks do not directly affect the reward-risk principle:

  • Credit risk: It is well-established in the fiqh literature that credit risk can be mitigated through kafālah (guarantees) or rahn (collateral), be it credit arising out of a sale, lease or some other contractual forms (Al-Zuḥaily, 1984). Other similar risks faced by IFIs in financing activities include counterparty and default risks, which have similar implications.

  • Business risk: It is inherent and internal to every business, including IF business and cannot possibly be averted fully, but it is rather managed. However, one of the most important components of business risk is market and ownership risk, meaning that business risk is a result of the aggregation of such risks – a broader category that concerns institutions rather than individual transactors as was the context in which fiqh developed (Awidha, 2010; Dusuki, 2016). Muhammad et al. (2015) affirm that such risks in IF are shared by financiers and financing recipients (customers) as in the case of muḍārabah and mushārakah financing, at least theoretically. In the case of ribā-based financing, such risks are generally borne by (transferred to) the borrowing customers and not the lenders (Dusuki, 2016).

  • Fiduciary risk: In the form of negligence or breach of terms, it is mitigable by the nature of Sharīʿah contracts through the imposition of ḍamānāt (indemnities) and taʿwiḍāt (compensations). The fiduciary risk may take the form of market risk when investment account holders (IAH) do not receive the expected market return, as investment accounts are a muḍārabah-type investment by the customer (rabb al-māl) in which the IB is the muḍārib managing the funds (Dusuki, 2016). It may, in this regard, be mitigated when a loss is due to negligence (ihmāl) by the muḍārib. Other risks interact with fiduciary risk; for example, Sharīʿah non-compliance risk, as it is related to complying with Islamic requirements for IFIs to conduct their business in the best interest of their stakeholders through the facilities of a Sharīʿah advisory board (Archer and Karim, 2007).

  • Other risks: Sharīʿah non-compliance risk does not have a direct bearing on the reward-risk equation as it pertains to distribution. Mark-up and price risks share features of market risk (Archer and Karim, 2007). Equity investment risk is a product of a series of the aforementioned risks, especially market risk, as the equity investments of banks on their trade books, for example, depending on market prices. Equity investment risk is also present in investment banking and private equity businesses of IBs which means that their value is influenced by market factors, among other things (Dusuki, 2016). Operational risk, according to Dusuki (2016), maybe accepted or avoided. In other words, it may be managed by the skill of the muḍārib. Various other risks exist; the foregoing discussion is for illustrative purposes and is not an exhaustive discussion of risk.

To sum up the parameter of risk, the current claim is that achieving justice in financial dealings involving Islamic contracts of market exchange is done through equitably apportioning reward and risk. The focus is set on market and ownership risk where other risks may or may not be directly relevant. Capital loss risk is related to the māl parameter, which shall be discussed shortly.

Ḍamān and risk

Ḍamān is an Arabic word that refers to liability or guarantee (Abū Ḥārith, 2003). It appears in the ḥadīth and the maxim derived from it: al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān. In another tradition, yuḍman, another derivative of the same root, is used: ribḥu mā lā yuḍman (the profit of that for which no liability is assumed). In either case, al-Zarqā (1989) ties it to the liability of loss which entitles the owner to kharāj, which he defines as any product of the asset that is separate from the asset.

For the purpose of this study, the latter meaning is the one intended; that is, the possibility of having to guarantee the loss or damage of capital, be it physical or financial. If it is owned by the party responsible for ḍamān, then such a party is required to bear the risk of losing its capital. Put differently, as the jurist Abū al-Faḍl (1937) argues, ḍamān follows (is bound to) ownership. In fact, jurists in general establish that ḍamān in this case refers to bearing the risk of loss of capital, be it physical or financial (Al-Zuḥaily, 1984; Abū Ḥārith, 2003). Al-Ṣadr (1981) uses the terms ḍamān and mukhāṭarah (risk) interchangeably but emphasizes that the focus is on the ownership itself that entitles the owner to an income and not the risk. What has been discussed under the topic of risk is then a discussion of ḍamān itself, and it does not appear that ḍamān requires further elaboration.

Costs and reward-risk

In financing assets, whether through the participatory (equity) approach or through the pure financial intermediation approach, costs related to an asset or venture financing are an important consideration as overburdening one party with certain costs could throw the reward-risk equation off balance. In the case of production, Shaḥātah (2020) makes the argument that anything unrelated to the production of the asset, such as the personal expenses of the producer, is not included in its costs. This is only fair as a potential buyer pays for the asset and its related costs, and is not responsible for the finances of the producer. The discussion of acquiring or producing an asset and its related acquisition costs is relevant to costs in financing assets, as the financing transaction should be independent of the financing entity. The personal finances of the financier should not influence the financing transaction between the financier and the recipient of financing (Shaḥātah, 2020). This has real implications on distributing costs, risks and rewards that relate to IB financing activities.

Jurists have elaborated on the topic of contractual expenses and who should bear which expenses. Examples of that are cited in Al-Zuḥaily (2006), but not in the context of financing by financial intermediaries, as the latter is alien to the juristic literature (Kahf, 2006). Chapra (1985) claims that financiers may charge only out-of-pocket expenses to their customers unless PLS modes are used, as PLS modes require that expenses be subtracted from the capital of the mushārakah. That is not the case, however, with non-financing activities where the IB may charge customers both out-of-pocket expenses and opportunity costs – such as in remittance services. The rationale behind this is that in the former case, the IB and customer stand to profit and should, thus, bear the costs equitably. In the latter case, it is the customers only that benefit from these services and should, thus, bear the expenses related to them. Put another way, realistically, the IB must ultimately earn a return in excess of the expenses from offering such services or else it would not offer them. According to Chapra’s opinion, out-of-pocket expenses may include costs of acquiring assets, as in MPO or insuring and maintaining the asset, as in AITAB. In the scope of sale and lease financing methods, ownership is relevant as is evident from the literature review. Expenses related to ownership are borne by the owner, such as insurance for delivery of the asset from the third party to the IB in an MPO and such as insurance costs of the asset being leased in an AITAB. This is because, in both cases, the asset is considered to be under the ownership of the financier (Chapra, 1985; IIFA, 2000; Kamali, 2007; Awidha, 2010; BNM, 2010; AAOIFI, 2017).

In partnership modes of financing, the mutual nature of the contract entails the sharing of costs, as they are the main impediment to realizing profits. This is done by subtracting them from total returns to arrive at the profit that will be distributed to the partners and managers. In ascertaining which costs relate to the income and which do not, al-Shāʿir (2010) establishes that jurists left their determination to the custom of traders at the time. Ascertaining such expenses was relatively easy and small in scope in earlier times, but today’s setting in IB has changed drastically. As a practitioner and a member of the Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI), al-Shāʿir (2010) affirms that different IFIs have factored in different expenses in calculating net profits to be distributed to IAHs. He gives examples of the kinds of expenses that are subtracted from total income and those that are subtracted specifically from the IAHs’ share of profits. Although it is not the purpose of this section to criticize industry practice, al-Shāʿir does convey his concern regarding the fairness of the practice and its integrity. Other criticisms of cost distribution in partnership-based IB financing are that the financier in an MMP may impose on the customer taxes and other expenses that should ideally be shared between them (Meera and Razak, 2005). However, the difference between the MMP and muḍārabah-based investment accounts is that the asset being financed in the MMP is co-owned by the IB and the customer, and hence causes greater problems in apportioning responsibility for expenses (Meera and Razak, 2005, 2009; Azma et al., 2014; Zabri and Mohammed, 2018).

Still, other views exist to challenge these, such as the fact that jurists have more often than not resorted to ʿurf (industry convention) in determining the fair distribution of costs. They argue that the same would apply in the determination of asset cost in MPO (Eid, 2011) and who bears maintenance and insurance costs in AITAB. Kahf (2020b) affirms that they are ownership-related expenses, but they may be charged to the customer. Besides major ownership-related expenses such as insurance, no definitive principle or consensus opinion exists for the division of costs. In principle, costs reduce total income from a transaction and so directly affect kharāj. Equitability in apportioning them seems to be best determined by inferring from the previously cited sources, namely, by what industry convention deems fit, as long as fairness is upheld.

Work, effort and adding value

The next parameter of reward-risk is adding value, which refers to the economic value added through IF transactions. IB financing transactions involve property in the form of physical capital (assets) or monetary capital (equity). If relevant risks are present in the financing transaction, it is considered value-adding. It is claimed that this is because bearing risk is the way to add value to the economy. Relevant risks include ownership risk, market risk and capital loss risk (which shall be discussed later under the parameter of māl). The following is a presentation of relevant scholarly opinions on the parameter of effort and added value.

In the fiqh tradition, ʿamal (labor/work) that entails exertion is an established economic factor that entitles the āmil (laborer/worker) to fair compensation (al-Kāsānī, 1986). Al-Ṣadr (1981) opined that a muḍārib may not advance the capital given to him by the rabb al-māl to another muḍārib on the basis that the latter muḍārib earns a percentage less than that which the former muḍārib earns. Put simply, entrepreneur A advances venture capital to entrepreneur B and earns a profit from it that is not justified as A did not exert any effort to realize added value. Al-Ṣadr likened this to A (e.g. the IB) taking the difference of profits received from B (recipient of financing) and those distributed to the initial rabb al-māl (IAHs) without the real effort involved on the part of A. This is clear evidence that the earliest contemporary Islamic economics did indeed observe ʿamal as a fair requirement for compensating labor factors of production (which some require that IFIs replicate). In the case of ʿamal done by the ajīr (hired labor), it is to be fairly compensated if it is completed, even if there is a disagreement between the contracting parties or a nullification of the labor contract. Payment shall be according to the prevalent rates, although there are some disagreements among jurists on the detailed rulings (Al-Zuḥaily, 1984; al-Quradaghi, 1988). The preceding opinions are generalized to include the effort of all sorts and not just muḍārabah and labor contracts. Abdullah (2015) views that amal, which is synonymous with kasb (earning), entitles one to counter-value. This is synonymous, according to some literature, with the addition of value (Rosly, 2001; Rosly and Sanusi, 2001). This concept of adding value, which ties transactions to the real economy, is prevalent in IF literature and further associated with reward-risk (Rosly, 2001; Rosly and Sanusi, 2001; Kahf, 2006; Asutay, 2008). These opinions converge on the importance of effort in IF transactions.

Two important points can be inferred from this brief discussion regarding this parameter of reward-risk. First, work or effort is a factor, which should be rewarded with wages or some other form of compensation, and secondly, it should be done fairly so as to realize fairness and justice. Al-Quradaghi (1988) establishes that the objective of ʿiwaḍ al-mithl (standard compensation) is the realization of justice. This is extended to include the compensation of work and effort through ajr al-mithl (standard wage/fee). An analogy is drawn between this and other cases such as muḍārabah where the muḍārib is compensated according to the profit share for his efforts and risk-taking. This is extended to other forms of risk-taking including ownership and the taking of market risk. This is evident in IB financing products, which do not directly involve physical effort but involve effort in risky forms of financing services rendered by the IFI such as sale- and lease-based financing. The issue lies with the substance of these products and whether they ultimately expose the IB to ownership and market risks. This contrasts with conventional economists’ opinions on added value. For example, a number of conventional economics researchers hold that the very activity of intermediation and bringing sellers, buyers and financiers together is the essence of the value added by banks and other financial intermediaries (Wang, 2011; Alon et al., 2011).

There still does not seem to be a single unified definition of added value among IF researchers. Hence, the following is an attempt to connect the dots from the preceding discussion:

  • Rosly (2001) links added value to the effort.

  • Kahf (2006) views added value in contrast with pure wealth transfer (such as through ribā-based finance). Other prominent IF experts such as Khan (1994) also emphasize this point.

  • The common denominator of Rosly (2001) and Kahf’s (2006) propositions seems to be the presence of effort and risk.

  • Suharto (2014) cites effort as a factor in trade (bayʿ) in which risk, and not just time value, entitles the seller to a profit on the sale. If the risk is present, the seller is entitled to a mark-up profit because he sold the asset on a deferred payment basis (extending credit to the buyer).

  • Furthermore, there is an emphasis on risk-taking ventures such as muḍārabah and their link to added value by both prominent and lesser-known IF researchers (Rosly, 2001; Rosly and Sanusi, 2001; Kahf, 2002; Asutay, 2008; Gulzar and Masih, 2015; Hussain et al., 2016).

Relating this discussion back to the parameter that is to be established for reward-risk, it can be noted that:

  • Amal is directly related to adding value.

  • Adding value through risk-taking entitles the risk-taking party to fair earnings or reward. In a sale or lease, this takes the form of ownership and market risks. In muḍārabah and mushārakah, it takes the form of loss of effort and capital loss risk. This can be extended to any other exchange-type fiqh contract.

  • Risk is inherent in any commercial activity that adds value, thus entitling the bearer of risk to income.

  • An example of this is embodied in the essential Sharīʿah prohibition of ribā, in that the lender does not risk its capital and effortlessly ensures a profitable return adding no value as a financier in the transaction. This is contrasted with the other forms of contracts such as sale, lease and muḍārabah, which involve a degree of risk.

Māl (capital)

In IF, the idea of capital is derived from the Islamic economics understanding of māl. Capital can take physical or monetary form. It can also take the form of credit such as in salam (forward) and istiṣnāʿ (construction) sales or equity, such as in muḍārabah. Various fiqh works and compendiums like those developed by the Ministry of Awqaf and Islamic Affairs (1983) and Al-Zuḥaily (1984) cite the juristic rule that the entitlement to profit by the profiting party requires the party to either expend effort, assume ḍamān or commit māl. This is traced back to a Ḥanafī principle articulated by al-Kāsānī (1986) and others. It is important to note, however, that when capital is considered a factor which entitles its owner to a return, it is not because of the money itself, but rather the money which, through turnover, is turned into goods and services. The goods and services are further sold for a counter-value which may result in a profit (capital gain) or loss (capital loss). Put more simply, the owner of capital is the owner of the goods and services being bought and sold using that capital (al-Ṣadr, 1981; Kahf, 2002). It is understood from this point that the risk of using capital affects the owners of capital directly. This is what is referred to as capital loss risk. IBs, as the owners of capital, are subject to this risk to justify their income if equity-based methods that use capital are used for financing.

This contrasts with ribā-based lending, which is capital in the form of monetary credit advanced to another party. The capital is still owned by the lender and is guaranteed by the borrower, along with the mandatory interest payments. This implies that the risk of lending does not affect the lender directly, but rather impacts the borrower who is obliged to repay the debt regardless of his business’s outcome. Lending at interest affects the lender indirectly through credit risk and opportunity cost that is lost in case the lender fails to recuperate the value of his loan. IF takes ribā-based lending and transforms it into equity-based financing – at least in theory, as it is not necessarily used in practice. Other forms of financing such as sale- and lease-based financing also fulfill the objective of justice and provide an alternate to ribā-based lending through observing the appropriate ownership risk and cost requirements discussed earlier.

In defining this parameter of reward-risk, an IFI provides financing to earn a return that will differ in nature based on the type of contract being used. Risk must be borne by the financier, be it in the form of ownership risk of physical assets or equity risk in the form of māl invested into the venture of a customer (Kahf, 2002). This is not to say that risk is sought after in IF (Kahf, 2006; al-Suwailem, 2006), but rather it is a way to compensate the owner of the capital. Otherwise, the other party would have to bear the risk while paying a price for financing, which is a form of ribā. Risk is then evidence of ownership of māl, which is a means of earning a profit on such māl. In MMP, the case is a bit different, as the asset of the mushārakah is considered to share capital and in the case of a liquidation event, the asset is turned into monetary capital to be distributed among the partners, the IB and the customer. In this case, the rule is that the IB equitably shares the risk involved in the possible loss of capital with the customer, based on the share of each party. This is one proposition, with the other being that MMP is shirkat al-milk (co-ownership), whose parameters are not strictly defined by scholars.

Another important distinction is that profit on māl is justified if capital loss risk genuinely exists. Profit on a loan is ribā, as there is no capital loss risk on a loan – it is guaranteed. In both cases, capital is advanced as a form of financing, but the distinguishing factor is the risk, which renders the profit legitimate or not. This is difficult to demonstrate in IB financing today as IBs simply do not use equity capital for financing due to the high equity and capital loss risks involved.

Table 1 summarizes the preceding discussion and demonstrates an example of each parameter of reward and risk.

Conclusion and recommendations

In summary, reward-risk in IF is undoubtedly an important concept that has garnered much concern and criticism. It is claimed that the proposed parameters of reward-risk will achieve justice. They include consideration of market, ownership and capital loss risks, contractual costs and effort that adds value. There are alternate propositions that do not strictly uphold these parameters but also achieve justice.

The study discovers that ghurm, being the first parameter of reward-risk, can take various forms, from market or ownership risk to loss of expended effort. However, there are other risks that are inherent to exchange or market transactions that directly affect IFIs, and IB financing facilities in particular, but which are not considered to fall within the scope of the reward-risk principle.

Ḍamān is directly linked to risk, as it refers to bearing the risk of loss of capital, be it physical or financial and, as the terms ḍamān and mukhāṭarah (risk) have been used interchangeably by scholars. Costs reduce the income of the relevant party in a transaction and so directly affect kharāj (reward). Some have argued that apportioning costs must observe a fixed set of rules, but others argue that it may be dictated by industry convention as long as fairness is upheld. The concept of adding value means adding value to the economy, which is achieved by expending effort through some sort of risk-taking. This is a distinguishing feature of IF that differentiates it from the risk-free or effortless nature of interest-based lending in conventional finance. Ownership of māl is also a parameter which is evidenced by the presence of capital loss risk in equity-based financing transactions; otherwise, they would not be different from a risk-free ribā loan.

Each of the parameters contains a set of conditions to be considered when using IF to ensure the financing transaction is fair and just. As is evident from the research, industry practice has consistently avoided the proper observance of these parameters while advocates of the proper application of reward-risk have been ardent in reinstating the importance of them and the necessity of adhering to their specific forms. This raises the question of whether it is allowed for such parameters to be adapted to the innovative and flexible nature of IF transactions, especially in financing activities, as advanced by some of the competing opinions that have been presented in this study.

In that light, it is recommended that the following areas and propositions be looked into further and given serious consideration in future research:

  • A novel model of Islamic financial intermediation based on a positive analysis of the greater global financial landscape is required. This may help define an alternate pragmatic set of parameters for reward-risk.

  • There needs to be a greater presence of maqāṣid-based reasoning which refers to scholarly conclusions and judgments based on the objectives of the Sharīʿah and which allows for multi-dimensional reward-risk considerations for Islamic financing products.

  • Relevant to the previous point, a more sophisticated framework of reward-risk needs to be laid down which is well-grounded in normative principles but adaptive to reality.

  • Critical approaches to the existing classical fiqh and contemporary literature are required to maintain the relevance of the Sharīʿah to the ever-evolving nature of finance and other aspects of life.

  • A critical approach to the nominate contractual forms is called for to determine their malleability – which principles stand and which do not – in developing hybrid and composite Sharīʿah contracts essential for today’s complicated and diverse financial and capital mobility needs.

Figures

Reward-risk illustrations of MPO, AITAB and MMP

Figure 1.

Reward-risk illustrations of MPO, AITAB and MMP

Proposed theoretical parameters of the reward-risk principle

ElementRemarkExample
ʿIwaḍ This is the concept of fair counter-value which pervades Islamic exchange dealings of economic agents including financiers and recipient of financings An asset sold is exchanged for the price paid. An asset’s usufruct is granted temporarily for rental payments paid
Risk It refers mainly to the risk of an uncertain outcome related to asset ownership or the buying and selling of assets in the market. It concerns ownership, market and capital loss risk. Risk varies: some forms may be mitigated, other forms may not; yet others are unavoidable and may only be managed Ownership risk occurs when possessing inventory that cannot be sold or is sold at a loss or which may be subject to loss including damage or destruction. IBs subject themselves to ownership risk in selling assets such as property and vehicles and – theoretically – in financing venture enterprises which impact on their returns
Ḍamān The liability of bearing the aforementioned risks rests upon the transacting agents equitably according to the contractual forms undertaken The asset vendor in an MPO/AITAB financing will bear the liability of destruction of the asset as it is the actual owner. In MMP financing, the bank and customer as partners will equitably bear the loss of contributed assets/capital in the case of destruction of the asset being financed
Value-adding Effort leads to adding value and is indicative of real economy contact and inherently entails the bearing of risks (ownership, market and capital loss) In a ribā-based loan, no value is added as a loan is made, pursuant to which the principal and an increment are returned with no risk to the lender. In a valid (permissible) sale, the asset is sold at a mark-up price facilitating a trade transaction between producers and consumers; the vendor would bear the risk. A partnership-based financing mode also adds value through the facilitation of trade or business. Risk is evident in either form of financing
Māl Māl, as a factor of production, is subject to risk as other assets are. Māl is used to finance assets, projects and ventures which represent activities that bear capital loss risks to the owners of capital (partners/muḍārib) In an MMP, the IB uses its funds to purchase an asset, which is then contributed to the mushārakah, with the customer contributing a percentage of his/her own monetary capital. Both are forms of capital that are staked in a mushārakah

Source: Author’s own

References

AAOIFI (2017), Sharīʿah Standards, Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions, Manama.

Abdullah, A. (2015), Fundamentals of Islamic Economics, International Council of Islamic Finance Educators, Kuala Lumpur.

Abdullah, A. (2016), “Examining US approvals of Islamic financing products and the Islamic theory of lawful profit”, International Journal of Islamic and Middle Eastern Finance and Management, Vol. 9 No. 4, pp. 532-550.

Abojeib, M., Haneef, M.A.M. and Mohammed, M.O. (Eds) (2018), Islamic Economics: Principles and Analysis, International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance, Kuala Lumpur.

Abū Al-Faḍl, M. (1937), Al-Ikhtiyār li Taʿlīl al-Mukhtār, Maṭbaʿat al-Ḥalabī, Cairo.

Abū Ḥārith, M.S. (2003), Mawsūʿat al-Qawāʿid al-Fiqhiyyah, Muʾassasat al-Risālah, Beirut.

Al-Ashqar, M.S. (1998), “Al-Ḍawābit al-latī taḥkumu ʿaqd ṣiyānah al-aʿyān al-muʾajjarah”, in Ashqar, M.S., Shabir, M.S., Majid, M.A.R. and Umar S.A. (Eds), Buḥūth Fiqhiyyah fī Qaḍāyā Iqtiṣādiyyah Muʿāṣirah, Dār al-Nafāʾis, Amman, pp. 300-324.

Al-Kāsānī, A. (1986), Badāʾiʿ al-Ṣanāʾiʿ fī Tartīb al-Sharāʾiʿ, Dār al-Kutub al-ʿIlmiyyah.

Al-Khaṭṭābī, A.S.M. (1932), Maʿālim al-Sunan, al-Maṭbaʿah al-ʿIlmiyyah, Aleppo.

Alon, T., Fernald, J., Inklaar, R. and Wang, J.C. (2011), “What is the value of bank output?”, FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, available at: www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2011/may/value-bank-output/ (accessed 12 June 2019).

Al-Quradaghi, A.M. (1988), “Naẓariyyat ʿiwaḍ al-mithl wa atharuhā ʿalā al-ḥuqūq”, Ḥawliyyat Kulliyat al-Sharīʿah wa al-Dirāsāt al-Islāmiyyah, Vol. 1 No. 6, pp. 391-440.

Al-Ṣadr, M.B. (1981), Iqtiṣādunā, Dār al-Taʿāruf li al-Maṭbūʿāt, Beirut.

Al-Sālūs, A.A. (1995), “Hal yajūzu taḥdīd ribḥ rabb al-māl fī sharikah al-muḍārabah bi miqdār muʿayyan min al-māl”, Majallat Majmaʿ al-Fiqh al-Islāmī, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 143-229.

Al-Shāʿir, S. (2010), “Ihtisab al-ribḥ fī al-muḍārabah wa al-mushārakah fī hal khalṭ amwāl al-muḍārabah wa al-mushārakah”, paper presented at AAOIFI conference on Sharīʿah Board of Islamic Financial Institutions, 26-27 May 2010, Bahrain, available at: www.imtithal.com/uploaded/media/research/733احتساب-الربح-في-المضاربة-والمشاركة-في-حال-خلط-أموال-المضاربة-والمشاركة-د.-سمير-الشاعر.pdf (accessed 20 June 2019).

Al-Suwailem, S. (2006), “Hedging in Islamic finance”, Occasional Paper No. 10, Islamic Development Bank, Islamic Research and Training Institute, available at: www.academia.edu/1131359/Hedging_in_Islamic_finance (accessed 29 May 2019).

Al-Tirmidhī, M.B.I. (1975), Sunan al-Tirmidhī, Maṭbaʿat Muṣṭafā al-Bābī al-Ḥalabī wa Awlāduh, Cairo, Vol. 3.

Al-Zarqā, A.M. (1989), Sharḥ al-Qawāʿid al-Fiqhiyyah, Dār al-Qalam, Damascus.

Al-Zuḥaily, W. (1984), al-Fiqh al-Islāmī wa Adillatuh, Dār al-Fikr, Damascus, Vols 4/5.

Al-Zuḥaily, M.M. (2006), Al-Qawāʿid al-Fiqhiyyah wa Taṭbīqātuhā fī al-Madhāhib al-Arbaʿah, Dār al-Fikr, Damascus.

Archer, S. and Karim, R.A.A. (Eds) (2007), Islamic Finance: The Regulatory Challenge, Vol. 394, John Wiley and Sons.

Askari, H., Iqbal, Z., Krichene, N. and Mirakhor, A. (2012), Risk Sharing in Finance: The Islamic Finance Alternative, John Wiley.

Asutay, M. (2008), “Islamic banking and finance: social failure”, New Horizon, Vol. 169, pp. 1-3.

Awidha, A.A. (2010), Naẓariyyat al-Mukhāṭarah fī al-Iqtiṣād al-Islāmī, International Institute of Islamic Thought (IIIT), Herndon and London.

Azma, N., Rahman, M. and Albaity, M. (2014), “Issues and prospects of Islamic hire purchase financing: Malaysian evidence”, Journal of Management Research, Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 12-24.

BNM (2010), Shariah Resolutions in Islamic Finance, Bank Negara Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur.

Chapra, M.U. (1985), Towards a Just Monetary System, The Islamic Foundation, Leicester.

Chapra, M.U. (1992), “Islam and the economic challenge”, (No. 17), International Institute of Islamic Thought (IIIT), available at: http://ierc.sbu.ac.ir/File/Article/Islam%20and%20the%20Economic%20Challenge_93524.pdf (accessed 20 April 2019).

Choudhury, M.A. (1986), Contributions to Islamic Economic Theory: A Study in Social Economics, Palgrave Macmillan UK, London.

Dusuki, A.W. (2010), “Can Bursa Malaysia’s Suq Al-Sila' (commodity murabahah house) resolve the controversy over tawarruq?”, Research Paper, No. 10/20, International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance, Kuala Lumpur.

Dusuki, A.W. (Ed.), (2016), Islamic Financial System: Principles and Operations, International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance, Kuala Lumpur.

Eid, A.A. (2011), Naẓariyat al-Ribḥ wa Taṭbīqatuhā fī Muʿamalat al-Maṣārif al-Islāmiyyah: Dirāsah Muqāranah, Dār al-Fikr al-Jāmiʿī, Alexandria.

El-Hawary, D., Grais, W. and Iqbal, Z. (2007), “Diversity in the regulation of Islamic financial institutions”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 46 No. 5, pp. 778-800.

Gulzar, R. and Masih, M. (2015), “Islamic banking: 40 years later, still interest-based? Evidence from Malaysia”, available at: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/65840/1/MPRA_paper_65840.pdf (accessed 24 June 2019).

Hamoud, S.H. (1982), Taṭwīr al-Aʿmāl al-Masrafiyyah bi mā Yattafiqu Maʿa al-Sharīʿah al-Islāmiyyah, Maṭbaʿat al-Sharq wa Maktabatuhā, Amman.

Holton, G.A. (2004), “Defining risk”, Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 60 No. 6, pp. 19-25.

Hussain, M., Shahmoradi, A. and Turk, R. (2016), “An overview of Islamic finance”, Journal of International Commerce, Economics and Policy, Vol. 7 No. 1, p. 1650003.

Ibn ʿabd Al-Barr, Y.I.A. (2000), Al-Iistidhkār, Dār al-Kutub al-ʿIlmiyyah, Beirut.

Ibn Qudāmah, M.A. (1968), Al-Mughnī, Cairo Library (Press), Cairo.

Ibn Rushd, M.I.A. (2004), Bidāyat al-Mujtahid wa Nihāyat al-Muqtaṣid, Dār Al-Hadith, Cairo.

IIFA (2000), “Qarār bi shaʾn al-ijārah al-muntahiyyah bi al-mālik”, available at: www.iifa-aifi.org/2061.html (accessed 28 March 2019).

Iqbal, Z. (1997), “Islamic financial systems”, Finance and Development, Vol. 34, pp. 42-45.

Iqbal, Z. (1999), “Financial engineering in Islamic finance”, Thunderbird International Business Review, Vol. 41 Nos 4/5, pp. 541-559.

Kahf, M. (2002), “Strategic trends in the Islamic banking and finance movement”, paper presented at Harvard Forum on Islamic Finance and Banking, 6-7 April, Harvard University, MA, available at: https://tinyurl.com/y4ba3mta (accessed 19 June 2019).

Kahf, M. (2006), “Maqasid al Shari’ah in the prohibition of riba and their implications for modern Islamic finance”, paper presented at IIUM International Conference on Maqasid al-Shari’ah, 9-10 August, Kuala Lumpur, available at: https://tinyurl.com/yyqadb57 (accessed 20 April 2019).

Kahf, M. (2020a), “Realism in Islamic economics”, available at: http://monzer.kahf.com/papers/english/Realism.pdf (accessed 8 April 2019).

Kahf, M. (2020b), “Arab Gambian Islamic bank liquidity management fund for Islamic banks”, available at: http://monzer.kahf.com/papers/english/Liquidity_Management.pdf (accessed 20 June 2019).

Kahf, M. and Khan, T. (1992), “Principles of Islamic financing”, Research Paper No. 16, Islamic Research and Training Institute, Jeddah.

Kamali, M.H. (2007), “A Sharīʿah analysis of issues in Islamic leasing”, Journal of King Abdulaziz University: Islamic Economics, Vol. 20 No. 1, pp. 3-22.

Khan, M.F. (1994), “Comparative economics of some Islamic financing techniques”, Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 35-68.

Khan, S.H. (2009), “Why tawarruq needs to go”, Islamic Finance News, 4 September, pp. 17-22, available at: www.assaif.org/content/download/9962/53909/file/Study%20-%20Why%20Tawarruq%20Needs%20To%20Go.pdf (accessed 11 June 2019).

Khan, S.R. (1987), Profit-and-Loss Sharing: An Islamic Experiment in Finance and Banking, Oxford University Press, New York, NY, NJ.

Mahmud, Y.S. (2019), “Ribḥu mā lā yuḍman”, majallat al-Iqtiṣād al-Islāmī”, available at: https://tinyurl.com/rwf9pxz (accessed 14 July 2019).

Mālik, B.A. (1985), Muwaṭṭaʾ al-Imām Mālik, Dār Iḥyāʾ al-Turāth al-ʿArabī, Beirut.

Meera, A.K.M. and Razak, D.A. (2005), “Islamic home financing through mushārakah mutanāqiṣah and al-bayʿ bithaman ājil contracts: a comparative analysis”, Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 5-30.

Meera, M.K.A. and Abdul Razak, D.A. (2009), “Home financing through the mushārakah mutanaqisah contracts: some practical issues”, Journal of King Abdulaziz University-Islamic Economics, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp. 121-143.

Muhammad, M., Sairally, S.B. and Habib, F. (Eds) (2015), Islamic Capital Markets: Principles and Practices, International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance, Kuala Lumpur.

Rosly, S.A. (2001), “Iwad as a requirement of lawful sale: a critical analysis”, International Journal of Economics, Management and Accounting, Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 187-201.

Rosly, S.A. and Sanusi, M. (2001), “Some issues of bay' al-'inah in Malaysian Islamic financial markets”, Arab Law Quarterly, Vol. 16 No. 3, pp. 263-280.

Shaḥātah, H. (2020), “Al-manhaj al-Islāmī li taḥdīd wa ḍabt wa tarshīd takālīf al-intāj”, available at: www.darelmashora.com/Default.aspx?DepartmentID=26 (accessed 19 June 2019).

Shariff, R.A.M. and Rahman, A.R.A. (2003), “An exploratory study of ijarah accounting practices in Malaysian financial institutions”, International Journal of Islamic Financial Services, Vol. 5 No. 3, pp. 1-15.

Suharto, U. (2014), “Analysis of the concept of Islamic choice (ikhtiyar) on opportunity cost and time value of money in Islamic economics and finance”, International Journal of Economics, Management and Accounting, Vol. 22 No. 2, pp. 1-20.

Suzuki, Y. and Miah, M.D. (2018), Dilemmas and Challenges in Islamic Finance, Routledge, London.

Wang, J.C. (2011), “What is the value added of banks?”, available at: https://voxeu.org/article/what-value-added-banks (accessed 12 June 2019).

Zabri, M.Z. and Mohammed, M.O. (2018), “Qualitative validation of a financially affordable Islamic home financing model”, ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance, Vol. 10 No. 2, pp. 143-161.

Further reading

Ministry of Awqaf and Islamic Affairs (2006), Al-Mawsūʿah al-Fiqhiyyah al-Kuwaytiyyah, Dār al-Salāsil, Kuwait.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to acknowledge the International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance (ISRA) for their sponsorship of his master’s studies and related works produced, such as this paper, during the period of his candidacy. The author would like to acknowledge the advice of his supervisor Prof Dr Rusni Hassan for her guidance on his academic endeavors, one of which is this paper.

Corresponding author

Mohamed Benaicha can be contacted at: mohamed.benaicha@hotmail.com

About the author

Mohamed Benaicha is currently a Master’s Candidate in Islamic finance at the Institute of Islamic Banking and Finance (IIiBF), International Islamic University Malaysia (IIUM). His formative studies include undergraduate studies at the University of Toronto in business management with a specialization in finance, as well as several Canadian investment industry certifications and registrations from the Canadian Securities Institute (Moody’s). He holds a bachelor’s degree in Fiqh and Usul al-Fiqh from IIUM’s Shari’ah Faculty (Islamic Revealed Knowledge). Some of his professional and academic experiences include trading and analysis at Title Trading and the Ontario Teachers’ Pension Plan in Toronto, as well as research assistance, workshop coordination in IIUM and ISRA.

Related articles