Incentivizing knowledge institutions for entrepreneurship and society

Sebastian Aparicio (Department of Business, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain) (Centre for Entrepreneurship and Social Innovation Research (CREIS), Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain)
Mathew (Mat) Hughes (School of Business, University of Leicester, Leicester, UK)
David Audretsch (O'Neill School of Public and Environmental Affairs, Indiana University Bloomington, Bloomington, Indiana, USA)
David Urbano (Department of Business, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain) (Centre for Entrepreneurship and Social Innovation Research (CREIS), Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain)

International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research

ISSN: 1355-2554

Article publication date: 29 March 2023

1049

Abstract

Purpose

Going beyond the traditional approach of formal and informal institutions as antecedents of entrepreneurship (directly) and development (indirectly), this paper seeks to explore knowledge institutions as a necessary input for entrepreneurship and the development of societies.

Design/methodology/approach

Institutional economics lenses are utilized to observe other factors (e.g. the number of R&D staff and researchers from the public sector) that involve laws and socialization processes, which at the same time create knowledge useful for entrepreneurs and society. These ideas are tested through a sample of 281 observations from 17 autonomous communities and two autonomous cities in Spain. The information coming from the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM), Ministry of Economics, Industry, and Competitiveness, and INE (Instituto Nacional de Estadística), was analyzed through 3SLS, which is useful for a simultaneous equation strategy.

Findings

Knowledge institutions such as the number of R&D staff and researchers from the public sector are found positively associated with entrepreneurship, which is a factor directly and positively linked to economic development across Spanish regions.

Originality/value

The findings help the operationalization of other institutions considered in institutional economics theory and its application to entrepreneurship research. Moreover, the results bring new insights into the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship in the public sector, in which the institutional analysis is implicit.

Keywords

Citation

Aparicio, S., Hughes, M.(M)., Audretsch, D. and Urbano, D. (2023), "Incentivizing knowledge institutions for entrepreneurship and society", International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJEBR-07-2022-0652

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, Sebastian Aparicio, Mathew (Mat) Hughes, David Audretsch and David Urbano

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


Introduction

Since its inception, entrepreneurship research has evolved from queries on the individual (psychological) and organizational (strategy) factors to contextual elements shaping decisions that involve risk and uncertainty (Audretsch, 2012; van Gelderen et al., 2021). The evolution of the field has also considered a tireless task in search of the benefits of undertaking a new entrepreneurial project. Results have ranged from personal realization, firm growth and macroeconomic gains such as competitiveness and development (Landström, 2020). Additional research has brought together the two main questions “why” and “to whom” by simultaneously analyzing the antecedents and consequences of entrepreneurship (Bjørnskov and Foss, 2016; Urbano et al., 2019). Thanks to this discussion, institutional factors have been put on the table as contemporaneous determinants of quantity and quality of entrepreneurship across regions and countries (Chowdhury et al., 2019), which in turn spur economic development over time (Aparicio et al., 2016; Bosma et al., 2018).

The institutional approach is, certainly, not new. Veciana and Urbano (2008) have introduced a complete special issue devoted to understanding those elements de facto and de jure that condition individual decisions toward entrepreneurship. Afterward, Bruton et al. (2010) have created a thorough piece of research analyzing the evolution of the institutional theory and its connection with entrepreneurship research. Such an analysis has served to expand our knowledge about not only types (formal and informal; or normative, cultural-cognitive and regulative, etc.) but also levels of institutions (macro, meso and micro). Despite these efforts, a common vision persists on what institutions mean for economic activities (including entrepreneurship) and society. That is, North (1990, p. 3) has defined institutions as “rules of the game that shape human interaction …” Yet, little research has gone beyond this definition and conducted analyses around institutions as a system of incentives for, among other activities, entrepreneurship (Baumol, 1990). Urbano et al. (2019) and Zhai et al. (2019) find that formal institutions have been massively explored as compared to informal ones. While informal rules complement formal institutions (Scott, 1995; Williamson, 2000), this research attempts to continue the analysis of the latter by going beyond regulations, procedures and taxes as proxies of formal institutions.

Recently published articles have started exploring institutions as a conducive set of (public) decisions that foster entrepreneurial activity. Bennett (2019), Foss et al. (2019) and Mickiewikz et al. (2021) have studied pro-market institutions that incentivize individuals to take the risks involved in the entrepreneurial process, and hence, participate in the labor market. Although these institutions commonly come from public policies, private entities end up mobilizing required resources to turn new ideas into entrepreneurial projects. Audretsch et al. (2020) and Audretsch and Link (2019) have opened a new pathway to explore the role of governments in implementing policies and acting actively in processes of knowledge generation, which imply the utilization of resources and the coordination of partnerships that guarantee the transition from ideas to marketplaces. Their idea is rooted in the notion of the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship (Acs et al., 2009, 2013), in which entrepreneurs become the agents capable of identifying and translating ideas into society through practical and innovative solutions. Under this perspective, knowledge becomes a resource (Hughes et al., 2021), which governments constantly feed. However, all the governmental efforts to acquire the funding that promotes research and development, as well as education also constitute a system of incentives that enables people to start new ventures. Peters and Besley (2008) have explored knowledge institutions beyond the typical role of universities in the entrepreneurial process. Accordingly, Peters and Besley (2008) have suggested that other organizations (e.g. government and firms) can also participate in the process of knowledge creation through laws, decrees and budget (in the case of governments), as well as investments (in the case of firms). As little evidence exists in this regard, it has been claimed for further analysis about those formal factors in the public sector that incentive the inception of ideas (Peters and Besley, 2008), which are lately absorbed by entrepreneurs (Audretsch and Link, 2019).

Hence, this paper seeks to explore knowledge institutions as a necessary input for entrepreneurship and the development of societies. Institutional economics (North, 1990, 2005) is the main framework that sets the basis, upon which knowledge, as an institution, incentivizes entrepreneurship that is directly linked to economic development. Spanish regions serve as a laboratory to explore these ideas. Hence, we use an unbalanced panel data that comprise 281 observations from 17 autonomous communities and two autonomous cities (Ceuta and Melilla) over the 2004–2018 period. Our findings support the idea that knowledge institutions such as the number of staff involved in R&D and researchers from the public sector increase the level of entrepreneurial activity, which is a mechanism directly and positively linked to economic development.

Based on our findings, we bring a series of implications for theory and policy. First, our research helps a further comprehension of institutions beyond the traditional view of formal rules such as regulations, permits and procedures. We materialize North’s (2005) ideas around knowledge as an institutional factor, which implies both laws to approve the budget for hiring public servants and socialization processes among R&D staff and researchers that result in new knowledge, hence, becoming a source of opportunities for the entrepreneurial identification. Second, Acs et al. (2009, 2013), for the private sector and Audretsch and Link (2019), for the public one, have approached these phenomena through the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. However, the institutional framework is still implicit in such analysis. We put together these two complementary (but disparate) perspectives by explicitly analyzing the existing intersection between them. And third, we close the story about economic development by contributing to Hausman’s (2016) view of knowledge as a source of economic and social progress. We add to this literature the idea that governments are also important for knowledge generation, and that entrepreneurs transfer it to society, hence increasing the level of economic development. From a public policy angle, all this requires the creation and consolidation of think-tanks, entrepreneurial universities and industrial doctoral programs.

After this introduction, the paper continues as follows. First, a theoretical ground around institutions, knowledge, entrepreneurship and development is explained. Next, the methodology, including the data and modeling approach, is described. Afterward, results are analyzed, and so are the discussion and implications for theory and policy. Finally, conclusions, limitations and future research directions are highlighted.

Theory and hypotheses

Main theoretical foundations

The core idea within institutional economics (North, 1990) is that individual actions tend to be uncoordinated, hence uncertainty is created when those actions affect others’ production and lifestyle. According to North (1990, 2005), institutions arise to mitigate such a problem by offering a set of written (i.e. formal) and unwritten (i.e. informal) rules, which become either incentives or barriers to performing a particular activity and spur the level of development. From here, literature has tried to further comprehend the formation, functioning and interaction of those that lately become incentives. Williamson (2000, p. 597), for example, has classified institutions into four levels, which range from those having slow change such as culture and customs to those changing rapidly, e.g. governance as well as resource allocation and employment.

A concern has existed to properly measure institutions, with a particular focus on formal and informal ones (cf. Voigt, 2013; Voigt, 2018). A bunch of projects has emerged to provide scholars and policymakers with the necessary tools for academic production and decision-making (see, for example, Djankov et al. (2002) for formal institutions; as well as Inglehart (1999) and Hofstede (2005) for informal factors). Implicit has been the treatment of knowledge as a stock of information common across society. Perhaps, we have interpreted Williamson’s (2000) levels three and four as a (public and private) organizational resource that spurs efficiency and competitiveness (see the perspectives by Dyer and Singh (1998) and Teece et al. (1997)). Yet, North (2005, pp. 20–21) has considered other types of institutions that are still part of the macro environment, by explaining that:

… the law merchant, patent laws, the institutional integration of distributed knowledge, the creation of a judicial system, have been important parts of efforts making markets more efficient in developed countries. And they are leading us into an unknown world of future uncertainties. When such institutional changes are applied to third world economies they frequently alter income distribution and produce political instability, sometimes leading to downstream consequences that are the very reverse of the intended objective.

These ideas have opened the possibility to explore and comprehend how entrepreneurs make decisions embedded in different environments (Baumol, 1990). Entrepreneurship research has grown thanks to this perspective, even though most of the literature has paid attention to the distinction between formal and informal institutions, affecting entrepreneurial activity, directly; and economic development, indirectly (Bruton et al., 2010; Bjørnskov and Foss, 2016; Urbano et al., 2019). While informal factors such as culture are the roots of any (entrepreneurial) society (Audretsch, 2007), formal institutions have played an important role in the entrepreneurial process and dynamics. Amorós et al. (2019a, b), Dau and Cazurra (2014), and McMullen et al. (2008) have discussed how the rapid change of formal institutions constitutes a policy mechanism that governments utilize to foster entrepreneurship. Governmental actions range from infrastructure, supportive policies and financial assistance for entrepreneurs (Amorós et al., 2019a, b; McMullen et al., 2008) to the creation and management of places such as universities and laboratories where people (i.e. researchers and academic staff) exchange ideas to create knowledge useful for entrepreneurs and society (Link, 2021).

Not precisely utilizing institutional economics, Acs et al. (2009, 2013) have considered knowledge as a contextual factor, which becomes a source of opportunities for people to work on entrepreneurial projects and bring benefits to society. This knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship has mostly relied on incumbent firms’ capacity to create new knowledge. However, recent advances have extended this notion to the public sector. Although governments could be assumed as regulators affecting firm entry (Djankov et al., 2002; van Stel et al., 2007), this paper goes beyond the traditional vision and subscribes to the emerging trend, in which the public sector is an institution a la North (1990, 2005) that incentivizes knowledge (Audretsch and Link, 2019; Demircioglu and Chowdhury, 2021; Link, 2021).

When it comes to knowledge institutions, literature has explored the role of universities as entrepreneurial entities leveraging economic growth (Klofsten et al., 2019). However, Peters and Besley (2008, p. 99) have explained that “[the] question should turn analysis away from the focus on the firm toward a better understanding of knowledge institutions, particularly universities but also research institutes, libraries, museums and galleries, as the primary ideas institutions.” For Peters and Besley (2008, p. 101), these are central factors, that “… illustrate how the discussion of institutional design, especially for universities and other knowledge institutions, needs to acknowledge the emerging liberal political economy of commons-based peer production which arguably has always had a central role to play in the production of knowledge…” This analysis sets the basis for exploring knowledge institutions as antecedents of entrepreneurship.

Hypothesis development

Drawing on Audretsch and Link (2019), Link (2021) and Peters and Besley (2008), we are interested in understanding how knowledge is also part of the connection between institutions and entrepreneurship. Similar to the private sector, knowledge generation requires important endeavors in collecting funds to support this activity, but above all, to increase and maintain a solid group of people involved in R&D (Link and Wright, 2015). Key activities from local governments may consist of creating public organizations fully orchestrated by the public sector, which are devoted to the development of products, services and processes, oriented to bring solutions into the communities that are part of the same region (Del Rey and Lopez-Garcia, 2020). For example, Arenas et al. (2020) have explored a public organization in Colombia completely focused on innovation. An important conclusion from Arenas et al.’s (2020) study is the importance of investing in human capital as the main core of this organization. Likewise, Civera et al. (2021) show that the knowledge created thanks to the indirect investment in R&D incentives people in Spain to become entrepreneurs with high growth potential. In general, the creation of laboratories and R&D departments of public-owned firms constitutes a decision that is supported by laws and decrees. Although Audretsch and Link (2019) identify places and activities as a source of knowledge, literature is still scarce. Yet, the reasoning behind the decision of hiring qualified personnel involved in R&D thanks to laws and decrees motivates us to posit that:

H1.

The number of public administration staff involved in R&D exerts a positive influence on entrepreneurship in Spain.

In line with the previous hypothesis, there is also a complementary activity that staff involved in knowledge generation constantly develops. While R&D activities entail the development of prototypes, these should be supported by theoretical analyses and advances. Thus, researchers devoted to exploring new theories, extant literature and results in other regions or countries become crucial to the creation of solid teams. Similar to R&D staff, researchers also create connections with industry and society through products such as academic articles, patents and so on (Aparicio et al., 2022a; Olcay and Bulu, 2017; Wong et al., 2007). Observing universities, this is clear as conducting research is part of their main activities (Culkin, 2016; Etzkowitz, 2017). Nonetheless, when observing public organizations, evidence of this idea remains scarce. Link and Scott (2021) provide evidence about the importance of having researchers in federal research laboratories, who create academic publications. These documents have two main functions. On the one hand, knowledge is disseminated to the rest of the academic community that builds prototypes or other innovative products upon that evidence. On the other hand, academic publications derived from research activities become the return to public-sector R&D (Link and Scott, 2021). Audretsch et al. (2019) also provide evidence about the role of innovation research centers in increasing a research team that produces academic articles. The key aspect here is the creation of knowledge that can be absorbed by entrepreneurs. Although the idea of knowledge spillover was focused on private companies (Acs et al., 2009), Audretsch and Link (2019) expanded the analysis to the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship in the public sector. In this regard, the origin of ideas that are transformed into products entrepreneurs commercialize comes from what researchers in public organizations such as research centers and universities perform. Therefore, a second hypothesis is suggested below.

H2.

The number of researchers in public administration exerts a positive influence on entrepreneurship in Spain.

The previous literature has served to disentangle the influence knowledge as an institutional factor may have on the formation of new ventures in Spain. Audretsch and Keilbach (2008) have discussed that the knowledge paradox not only encourages entrepreneurial activity but also serves to improve the competitiveness and economic development of regions and countries indirectly. Hausman (2016) has also suggested that knowledge and the way it is acquired explain development differences across regions and countries. In this regard, it seems knowledge is key for both entrepreneurship and economic development. To what extent does entrepreneurship become a mechanism between knowledge (as an institution) and development? There exist studies discussing the importance of institutions to spur entrepreneurship which, at the same time, is positively linked to growth and development in the long term (Aparicio et al., 2016; Bosma et al., 2018; Urbano et al., 2020). In general, the relationship between entrepreneurship and economic development at the regional and country level has been widely documented (Audretsch and Keilbach, 2008; Erken et al., 2018; Estrin et al., 2022; Fernandes et al., 2021; Liñán and Fernandez-Serrano, 2014). Even so, with the vast amount of evidence, the topic still draws the attention of different scholars in entrepreneurship, business, economics and management areas. Urbano et al. (2019) have found that most of the literature focuses on the national level. However, Kraus et al. (2021) have identified the need to continue exploring the effects that entrepreneurship may have on regional development. Particularly in Spain, González-Pernía and Peña-Legazkue (2015) and Gumbau Albert (2017) have provided empirical evidence on the importance of export-oriented and innovative entrepreneurship for higher regional development. Drawing on this evidence, one may assume that the effect of entrepreneurship on the Spanish economy is positive. Thus, we propose the following hypothesis:

H3.

Entrepreneurship, influenced by knowledge institutions, has a positive effect on the economic development in the Spanish context.

Data and methods

Dataset

To assess the previous hypotheses, we have employed annual data of 17 autonomous communities and two autonomous cities (Ceuta and Melilla), comprising a sample of 281 observations for the 2004–2018 period. Our unbalanced panel dataset consisted of combining information from Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM), Ministry of Economics, Industry, and Competitiveness, and INE (Instituto Nacional de Estadística). The GEM project is a complete dataset devoted to the exploration of entrepreneurial activity worldwide, its antecedents and its consequences (Bosma, 2013). Including more than 100 countries (both developed and developing), this dataset enables cross-national comparisons on the level of national entrepreneurial activity, as well as estimations of the role entrepreneurship plays in national economic growth. According to Acs et al. (2008), studies derived from GEM information have served to formulate and evaluate different public policies supporting innovation and entrepreneurship.

The existence of GEM national teams has enabled the collection of subnational data for some countries. This is the case in Spain, which counts with 26 teams covering all autonomous communities (Peña-Legazkue et al., 2020). Since we have focused on the Spanish case, complementary data come from official sources such as the Ministry of Economics, Industry, and Competitiveness, as well as INE, which provide details about the economy, population and public sector across the autonomous communities and cities over the last 20 years.

Variables and methodology

As we have hypothesized, entrepreneurship and regional development may be recursively interplaying, thus, it is necessary to decompose this sort of entrepreneurial activity into the following effects.

(1)Ln(Eit)=α+φLn(KIit)+βjJ=19Ln(Xj,it)+μit

To measure entrepreneurship (Eit) in the first stage, we follow Aparicio et al. (2016) and Bosma et al. (2018), who measure entrepreneurial activity by considering the percentage of the adult population involved in the creation of a new venture that is between 0 and 42 months (TEA), which is representative for the autonomous community or city i (from 1 to 19) and year t. While there are other indicators within the GEM project, Bosma (2013) explains that traditional entrepreneurship is properly approached through TEA, which embraces all types of drivers and characteristics. In essence, TEA becomes the starting point to know the level of entrepreneurial activity across regions and countries. Regarding those independent variables associated with knowledge institutions (KIit−1), Audretsch and Link (2019) and Link (2021) suggest that the number of staff involved in R&D and researchers represents the stock of rules (enabling enough budget for hiring the staff) and socialization processes (leading to innovation, ideas, etc.). Other scholars have had a similar approach by explaining entrepreneurial universities as other types of institutions (Culkin, 2016; Klofsten et al., 2019). Although the available budget is an important component, what matters in this research stream is the activities that give the entrepreneurial characteristic to universities. Audretsch and Link (2019) and Link (2021) help us understand another angle of the same phenomenon. That is, academic and R&D staff working in the public sector exist thanks to institutional incentives (laws and decrees) that promote knowledge, which is ultimately absorbed by entrepreneurs in the marketplace.

In the case of control variables (Xit−1), we have drawn upon Arin et al. (2015) to consider unobservable characteristics related to economic (number of existing firms, public administration expenditure in R&D, unemployment rate and GDP per capita) and demographic variables (the percentage of population with tertiary education, number of self-employees in industry, construction and service and the total population). The parameter μit represents the error of Equation (1).

To study the spread of entrepreneurship and its effects on regional development in a second stage, we investigate how entrepreneurs stimulate economic development, by estimating Equation (2):

(2)LnGDPit=θ+γ1LnE^it1+γ2LnR&Dit1+γ3LnKit1+γ4LnLit1+γ5LnGEit1+ωi+λt+εit

Here, the dependent variable in the second stage is GDPit, which is the constant value of the gross domestic product by autonomous community or city i in the period t (2004–2018). The estimated variable (E^it1) of Equation (1) is introduced in this stage, which means that the regional development is indirectly influenced by knowledge institutions. By following Aparicio et al. (2016), Audretsch and Keilbach (2008), Ferreira et al. (2017), González-Pernía and Peña-Legazkue (2015), traditional control variables in the augmented Cobb–Douglas production function are used. For instance, R&D expenditure (i.e. the governmental investment as a percentage of GDP), the stock of capital (invested by firms), the labor force (number of people actively participating in the labor market) and the government expenditure (as the constant value of the final consumption) are included. All data is converted into log form to make it smooth and easy to interpret (see Aparicio et al. (2016) and Wong et al. (2005) for further details). The main dependent and independent variables by autonomous communities and cities are shown in Appendix 1.

Given Equation (1) and Equation (2), a simultaneous modeling approach is used for the empirical purpose. For the estimation of these equations, a dynamic 3SLS is applied as it is more efficient than 2SLS as well as the traditional OLS approach. According to Zellner and Theil (1962), it is proved that the 3SLS allows the correlation between unobserved disturbances across various equations to be used in the analysis. This technique turns out to be more consistent and asymptotically normal. By considering certain conditions, 3SLS is even asymptotically more efficient than single equation estimates. It combines multivariate regression and two-stage regression (Zellner and Theil, 1962). Given its advantages, we have opted for the 3SLS method to analyze empirically the influence of knowledge institutions on entrepreneurship and simultaneously the changes in regional development when entrepreneurs vary over space and time. The description of each variable is shown in Table 1.

Results

Main findings

Table 2 provides the means, standard deviations and pairwise correlation coefficients for all the variables we assess in both equations. On the one hand, it is possible to observe that the average level of entrepreneurial activity across Spanish autonomous communities and cities is 5.59%, which is consistent with the GEM 2017–2018 national report (Peña-Legazkue et al., 2018). On the other hand, the correlation matrix shows potential associations between the variables used to capture knowledge institutions and entrepreneurship, which in turn is positively correlated with economic development, meeting our expectations. However, Table 2 also shows a high correlation between the three independent variables. Hence, we need to discard potential collinearity issues. A diagnostic test of multicollinearity was conducted through the variance inflation factors (VIFs) of all variables in the analyses for each model. After computing the test, we have found that variables are not problematic, since the obtained VIF was 3.07, a value substantially below 10, which is a suggested threshold (Hsieh et al., 2003).

In Table 3, the results of the 3SLS regression with robust variance estimates are shown. Following Carree and Thurik (2008) and Carree et al. (2002, 2007) and Urbano et al. (2020), we have accounted for business cycle effects such as crisis (González-Pernía et al., 2018) by including time-fixed effects. Thus, model 1 only estimates control variables in Equation (1) (education, number of firms, self-employees in industry, construction and service, as well as public administration expenditure in R&D, unemployment rate, GDP per capita and population). In addition to these controls, model 2 includes the first knowledge institution, which is the R&D staff in public administration. Model 3 replicates the same approach, but in this case, researchers in public administrations are considered a knowledge institution. Model 4 focuses on Equation (2) by independently estimating entrepreneurship, R&D expenditure, capital, labor force and government expenditure. Models 5 through 7 bring together Equation (1) and (2). For example, model 5 follows the same strategy as model 1. However, in this case, the entrepreneurship variable in Equation (2) was previously estimated in Equation (1) using only controls. Model 6 includes the first knowledge institutions (R&D staff in public administration), whereas model 7 considers the second knowledge institution (researchers in public administration). All the models are highly significant (p < 001), which means that the explanatory variables jointly explain the variance of entrepreneurial activity and economic development.

Concerning the suggested hypotheses, we have posited in hypothesis 1 that the number of public administration staff involved in R&D exerts a positive influence on entrepreneurship in Spain. Effectively, we found a positive effect of this knowledge institutions by observing that the number of people in the public administration working on R&D affected positively the total early-stage entrepreneurial activity in our sample (φ = 0.123, p < 0.1). Hence, we follow the statement presented by Link and Wright (2015), which suggests that endeavors in having a solid staff focused on R&D are translated into higher innovation and entrepreneurship. In fact, for each region in our sample, if the number of public administration staff involved in R&D increases by 1% through time, the level of entrepreneurship goes up by 0.123%, ceteris paribus. This result could indicate that public efforts in investing in R&D are important to engage more people in entrepreneurial activities.

Hypothesis 2 suggested that the number of researchers in public administration exerts a positive influence on entrepreneurship in Spain. The direction of this relationship was expected (φ = 0.140, p < 0.05). Based on our theoretical ground, it is possible to think that the number of researchers embraces different characteristics related to knowledge in each region in terms of the innovation process. According to Urbano et al. (2020), this type of intrapreneurial activity influenced by human capital tends to impact positively on firm growth. We find that for each region in our sample if researchers in public administration increased by 1% over time, the number of entrepreneurs increases by 0.140%, ceteris paribus. This might indicate that both public supports observed through the number of researchers and entrepreneurship are positively correlated. Extant literature emphasizes the importance of encouraging governments and universities to acquire an entrepreneurial mindset, so every strategic decision involving academic staff encompassing researchers, lecturers and practitioners yields the creation of social value (Wong et al., 2007).

In hypothesis 3, we posited that entrepreneurship, influenced by knowledge institutions, has a positive effect on the economic development in Spain. After introducing the lag of entrepreneurial activity into Equation (2), as an endogenous factor, our results provide support for not rejecting hypothesis (3). Effectively, models 6 and 7 show that entrepreneurship, influenced by the two types of knowledge institutions, positively affected Spanish regional development (γ1 = 0.013, p < 0.01 for both models). On the one hand, our findings are in line with the extant literature, which suggests that entrepreneurs, particularly those having close contact with R&D staff and researchers from the public sector, spur economic development (Acs et al., 2009; Audretsch and Link, 2019; Link, 2021). And on the other, the dynamic results we have obtained are following other studies comparing local entrepreneurship in Spain (González-Pernía and Peña-Legazkue, 2015). Here it is important to consider that, perhaps, entrepreneurs are more adapted to the environment, thanks to the knowledge in terms of markets, procedures, products and so on, which is generated under the government budget (Link, 2021). What turns out interesting from our exercise is that the positive correlation between entrepreneurship and regional development might imply that a larger number of entrepreneurs may be located in prosperous regions, as Liñan et al. (2011) have found. In fact, Spanish regions grow 0.013% on average when the level of entrepreneurship increases by 1%, ceteris paribus.

Finally, the analysis of control variables suggests that regions with a large portion of highly educated people may incentivize individuals to look for a job to avoid the risks associated with entrepreneurship, which is consistent with Berril et al. (2020) and van Stel and van der Zwan (2020). In addition, overcrowded markets (i.e. highly populated regions and many incumbent firms) bring opportunities in terms of available niches, which can become potential customers with purchase capacity (i.e. high GDP per capita). Consistent with the existing literature (Carree et al., 2002, 2007; Gries and Naudé, 2010; Hessels et al., 2008; Wennekers et al., 2005, among others). However, these markets can also impose barriers for new entrepreneurs. Hence, the tough competition may bring extra costs entrepreneurs might not be willing to assume (Bailey and Thomas, 2017). This is revealed through the negative and statistically significant effect of the number of firms on entrepreneurship.

Robustness check

To verify whether our models remain invariant when additional changes take place, we have conducted a series of robustness tests. We sought, therefore, to validate the key assumptions that we maintained when instrumenting for the entrepreneurship choice. Firstly, Table 3 shows consistency across models, in which estimations for independent and control variables hold when the latter is solely considered (model 1 and model 4), and when the former is included in the rest of the models. It is important to clarify that models 1 through 4 are performed using traditional OLS. We observe that the results neither lose some significance nor change in magnitudes.

Secondly, by following Aparicio et al. (2016) work, we have performed our models not only through 3SLS but also relying on 2SLS. As we have discussed in section 3, 3SLS turns out to be more efficient than OLS and 2SLS, nonetheless, we wanted to obtain a reference estimation through the basic two-stage method. Based on the results that we obtained (see Appendix 2), we have observed that the magnitude holds for all variables, and the standard error is lower for those models estimated with 3SLS than 2SLS. Additionally, we have computed the Hausman test to validate whether variations in the estimations obtained through 2SLS and 3SLS exist. We have found that it is not possible to reject the null hypothesis about the non-systematic differences in coefficients of the 3SLS as compared to the 2SLS estimation. This Hausman test guarantees that our structural model, estimated through different methods, is well specified, basically because there are no higher differences concerning both sign and magnitude.

Thirdly, since entrepreneurship may be measured through different indicators (Iversen et al., 2007), we changed our main dependent variable for Equation (1), which in turn is the main independent variable in Equation (2). Acs et al. (2008) have compared GEM data with World Bank information about newly registered firms. The authors have found that no systematic differences exist. Conducting a similar exercise, Margolis (2014) has shown that self-employment also represents individuals’ decisions about entrepreneurship. Although having new ventures is an important approach, we have opted for replacing total early-stage entrepreneurial activity from GEM with self-employment as it follows the same micro-foundations (Bosma, 2013). In our particular case, we have considered the percentage of the population that is self-employed. Information was taken from the Work and Social Affairs Ministry (Ministerio de Trabajo y Asuntos Sociales) during the 2004–2018 period, across 17 autonomous communities and two autonomous cities. As it can be seen in Appendix 3, even though the number of researchers in public administration is not statistically significant, results hold for both knowledge institutions and entrepreneurship. The lack of significance might be due to the association between self-employment and necessity-driven entrepreneurship (Muñoz-Mora et al., 2022; Puente et al., 2019).

Based on the findings from the checks described above, we believe that our results and specification remain stable to various changes applied to the original specification. Therefore, we are confident that the knowledge institutions we studied had a robust positive effect on entrepreneurship, which, in turn, affects Spanish regional development.

Discussion and implications

Our findings shed light on knowledge institutions for entrepreneurship and society. First, public servants focused on R&D activities urge entrepreneurship thanks to the knowledge they generate regularly. This result is aligned with the literature about innovation and entrepreneurship (Link and Scott, 2021; Link and Wright, 2015). However, in our case, knowledge comes through two main mechanisms, which are strongly associated with institutions. First, both communities and cities in Spain are autonomous when it comes to the definition of the public budget for all kinds of activities, including traditional consumption, R&D investment, acquisition of skilled personnel and ownership of firms. This budget is approved by law, which is directly related to the definition of an institution (North, 1990). The second mechanism is the socialization process among the staff working on R&D. It is well-known that innovative products and solutions are not created in isolation, hence teamwork is needed (Pinzón et al., 2021). These endeavors result in new technologies, methodologies, goods and services, which need an engine that translates them to the market. A firm-government partnership may enable such a transition (Klein et al., 2010). Yet, we are showing that entrepreneurs also absorb the remaining knowledge to bring social solutions.

Universities also play a key role in the partnership (Demircioglu and Audretsch, 2019). One of the main activities of higher education organizations is the constant work on theoretical and applied research. Audretsch and Belitski (2022) have suggested that universities are becoming entrepreneurial agents within the society as these organizations push the knowledge frontier thanks to research activities and include the society in their goal through (under)graduate programs. Our result for the number of researchers in the public sector goes in line with these ideas. This knowledge institution is also found an important element for entrepreneurship across Spanish regions. Similar to the staff involved in R&D, this factor also responds to the same mechanisms when it comes to the institutional analysis. Considering that most of the higher education organizations in Spain are public (Liñan et al., 2011), universities are certainly the main location where researchers perform their tasks and socialize with others to build up a conversation around new ideas. Laboratories publicly funded are also an appropriate environment for people to work on academic research, which feeds the foundation of new knowledge that entrepreneurs identify as potential market projects.

If innovations, prototypes and ideas at large coming from the public sector overcome the valley of death thanks to entrepreneurs (Takata et al., 2022), then society may obtain important benefits. Our results regarding the effect of entrepreneurship on regional development, effectively, indicate that having a certain number of people engaged in entrepreneurial activities is relevant for regional wealth in general. This can be explained in two ways. On the one hand, entrepreneurs bring new elements into Spanish regions and stimulate the opportunity identification through the existing knowledge in the environment. On the other hand, and as a possible consequence of the knowledge institutional setting, new entrepreneurs emerge to improve people’s needs and problems ranging from products that are still not available in the market to deep social inclusion (Aparicio et al., 2022b; Sulter et al., 2019). Thus, the relevance of generating incentives that urge entrepreneurs should be a priority, especially because there is a huge movement of younger generations, with entrepreneurial and technological skills, interested in solving economic, environmental and humanitarian problems through entrepreneurship. Our results, then, are practical in nature. However, scholars and policymakers can also benefit from some theoretical and public policy implications originated in our research.

Implications for theory and literature

A first theoretical implication consists of going beyond the traditional interpretation of institutions such as laws, regulations, culture and norms. North (2005, p. 21) recognizes that the existing knowledge in a society is also an institution, which provides incentives for economic and social development. We bring up these ideas to operationalize possible factors representing knowledge institutions as explained in Peters and Besley (2008). In both cases, R&D workers and researchers as staff of public administration are equipped with the necessary skills to expand knowledge and set the basis, upon which the society advances through better information, technology, health, etc. An example of this idea might consist of those efforts by the US government to enhance our understanding of the universe (Terjesen, 2016). The NASA, for instance, is a well-coordinated organization where skilled and qualified staff works constantly on solving complex problems, which lately is transferred to society through university programs.

Another way to create knowledge for the society consists of private initiatives that increase R&D as part of their strategies. Acs et al. (2009, 2013) have developed the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship, in which entrepreneurs are the catalyst of economic development thanks to their ability to identify opportunities and turn them into new ventures. Audretsch and Link (2019) and Link (2021) have extended this notion to the public sector, which is also able to create necessary knowledge that ultimately entrepreneurs absorb. Putting together institutional economics (North, 2005) and the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship in the public sector (Audretsch and Link, 2019) is precisely our second contribution to theory. It is undeniable the intersection between these frameworks, which implicitly have complemented each other. We explicitly suggest that the knowledge coming from public laws and subsequent investments is a source of inspiration for entrepreneurs, who contribute to economic development by bringing solutions to society.

Our third theoretical contribution is the role of entrepreneurs in the development process. Hausman (2016) has developed the scrabble theory of economic development, whose key element is the ability countries pose to create new knowledge helpful for the expansion of complex industries. Within this theory, foreigners play an important role to mobilize existing knowledge to other societies. Our results might complement this view in two ways. On the one hand, although it might take longer than Hausman’s (2016) idea, knowledge may also be a result of public and private initiatives. Indeed, public-private partnerships are ideal to provide enough funding for different innovative projects. On the other hand, unlike foreigners, entrepreneurs can play a role in the mobilization of ideas into real projects that help the expansion of existing industries and the integration with new ones.

Implications for policy

As per public policies, entrepreneurship gained attention back in the 2000s when the European Union aimed at improving industrial competitiveness and economic development across the region (Smallbone, 2016). Since then, entrepreneurship has become an engine to tackle different economic and social problems (Bacq et al., 2022). Governments have been interested in creating an appropriate environment where entrepreneurs make decisions with low risk and uncertainty (Arshed et al., 2014). Setting up ecosystems has become the priority when it comes to the association of institutions with entrepreneurship, which is assumed a leverage spurring economic development (Stam, 2015). Yet, some concerns have been raised, especially if the intention is to replicate the Silicon Valley model (cf. Audretsch, 2021). Pahnke and Welter (2019) have suggested that other types of ecosystems are equally important to incentivizing the creation and growth of small businesses. In this case, the role of governments has consisted of providing sufficient infrastructure that supports entrepreneurial dynamics. We complement this idea by emphasizing the governments’ role in not only the investment of infrastructure but also the staff and equipment they need to move forward research projects with theoretical and applied purposes.

Universities are primarily the vehicle to materialize these investments, especially because the basic infrastructure is already there. However, as part of the industrial policies under the ecosystems’ notion, governments are seeking a transition toward entrepreneurial universities, where people can acquire skills and abilities related to entrepreneurship (Audretsch and Belitski, 2022). The main goal is, therefore, to conceive universities as mechanisms that provide societies with an entrepreneurial mindset, increasing their entrepreneurial potential (Aparicio et al., 2021). Thanks to our findings, we suggest that other organizations different from universities can also complement the achievement of this mission. Think tanks and knowledge hubs have seemed to be good policies to improve industrial competitiveness and economic development. Arenas et al. (2020) have explained the case of RutaN in Colombia, which is a public organization working on R&D projects. This organization counts on skilled staff and scholars, who serve to build up a direct bride between them and the university system. Therefore, the scholars-for-universities notion is discarded thanks to our results.

Overcoming this myth entails the creation and consolidation of industrial doctoral programs (Brush et al., 2003; Pocek et al., 2022), which tackle social problems from companies’ needs. Certainly, a strong ecosystem requires the involvement of different stakeholders with social purposes (Spigel and Vinodrai, 2021). Incumbent companies are one of the key members to incentivizing and supporting people interested in becoming scientists and researchers. To achieve this, governments are called to play a role in this process and orchestrate people’s intentions, business preferences and university programs. The more available funding the higher the possibilities to involve others in the knowledge generation, useful for entrepreneurship and development.

Conclusions

In this paper, unbalanced panel data (for the period 2004–2018) were utilized to explore knowledge institutions as a necessary input for entrepreneurship and the development of societies. In doing so, a simultaneous equation model to enhance the comprehension of the interplay between these variables was used. Conceptually, we have approached knowledge institutions through the theoretical framework of institutional economics (North, 1990, 2005), which has served to analyze the influence of the number of R&D staff and researchers from the public sector on entrepreneurship, which at the same time took account of regional development in terms of the GDP level.

Regarding the institutional determinants of entrepreneurship, we found strong positive effects from all knowledge proxies. Both laws for public budgeting and socialization processes were the analyzed mechanisms behind the relationship between R&D staff and entrepreneurship. The same analysis was applied to the association between researchers from the public sector and entrepreneurial activity across Spanish regions. However, in this case, universities have also played a role in the formation of structures where socialization, and hence, knowledge may emerge.

Concerning the effect of entrepreneurship on regional development and society, we found that, effectively, the fact of having a certain number of entrepreneurs is relevant for regional wealth in general. This could be interpreted in two ways. On the one hand, the entrepreneurs embedded in societies with complex knowledge bring new elements to the Spanish culture and stimulate the opportunity identification through social ties. On the other hand, and as a possible consequence, skilled entrepreneurs emerge to improve the economy and society at large. Thus, the relevance of generating incentives that urge public-private partnerships useful for entrepreneurs should be a priority.

Before highlighting potential future research directions, we wish to acknowledge three key limitations to our study. First, although we rely on the number of R&D staff and researchers as a key institutional component, we still have a huge aggregation of groups from the public sector, especially for those related to key innovative activities. Unfortunately, the data we are using were not as rich as one would prefer. In this regard, we are not able to distinguish public servants from universities, public-owned companies, or public administration. However, similar to Aparicio et al. (2022a), we have assumed that the observed staff, despite different characteristics, share the public service feature, and hence, reflects scientific thinking and action. Secondly, our unit of analysis also suffers an important aggregation. Since we are using data only on the 17 autonomous communities and two autonomous cities, some details are escaping from our interpretation. For example, Andalucia, which is the biggest autonomous community, has slight differences among the towns that are part of it. Nevertheless, prior studies have provided important evidence about entrepreneurial activity at this aggregation level (Gumbau Albert, 2017; Liñán et al., 2011). Thirdly, our study only examines total early-stage entrepreneurs based on the GEM project. Since Spain has low levels of necessity entrepreneurship, this is not an inconvenience that biases our result.

Our study highlights some promising directions for future research. The first one has to do with the limitations mentioned before. New studies could take advantage of updated data released by INE, which consider not a group of economies, but countries individually. Additionally, particular differences within Spain might be captured by conducting studies at the province level, rather than at the autonomous community level. From a policy perspective, future studies could examine whether budgeting regulations change the desired investment in public staff devoted to R&D and research and subsequently create knowledge that inspires entrepreneurs. We, therefore, suggest future research which further explores the relationship between knowledge institutions, entrepreneurship and development at the regional and national levels. Future research might also consider other types of entrepreneurs (e.g. innovative, technological, export-oriented) as developed countries such as Spain are characterized by having different typologies of productive entrepreneurship (Amorós et al., 2019a; Dencker et al., 2019; McMullen et al., 2008). Other studies might focus on R&D staff and researchers from private universities as complimentary actors of public higher education organizations. While Spain is mainly characterized by the latter system, other countries such as the US or Latin America at large benefit from innovative endeavors in private universities. To this end, other techniques such as spatial econometrics might bring important insights into the debate.

Variables description

VariablesDescriptionSource
Equation (1)
Dependent variable
TEATotal early-stage entrepreneurial activity. Percentage of adults aged 18–64 setting up a business or owning–managing a young firm (up to 3.5 years old)GEM 2004–2018
Independent variables
Policy support
R&D staff in Public AdministrationNumber of staff involved in R&D in public administration by autonomous communityMinistry of Economics, Industry and Competitiveness 2004–2018
Researchers in Public AdministrationNumber of researchers in public administration by autonomous communityMinistry of Economics, Industry and Competitiveness 2004–2018
Control variables
EducationPercentage of population with tertiary education by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
FirmsNumber of firms within the autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Self-employees in industryNumber of self-employed workers in the industry sector by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Self-employees in constructionNumber of self-employed workers in the construction sector by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Self-employees in serviceNumber of self-employed workers in the service sector by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Public administration expenditure in R&DTotal expenditure of R&D by public administration in autonomous community (in thousand of Euros)Ministry of Economics, Industry and Competitiveness 2004–2018
Unemployment rateUnemployment rate by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
GDP per capitaTotal value of gross domestic product (GDP) per capita. Data in 2010 constant eurosINE 2004–2018
PopulationNumber of inhabitants by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Equation (2)
Dependent variable
GDPTotal value of gross domestic product (GDP) by autonomous community. Data in 2010 constant valuesINE 2004–2018
Independent variables
TEATotal early-stage entrepreneurial activity. Percentage of adults aged 18–64 setting up a business or owning–managing a young firm (up to 3.5 years old)GEM 2004–2018
R&D expenditureTotal expenditure of R&D as percentage of GDP approved by law. It includes firms and universitiesMinistry of Economics, Industry and Competitiveness 2006–2014
CapitalTotal gross capital formation by firms in autonomous community. Data in 2010 constant eurosINE 2004–2018
Labor forceNumber of people with a job by autonomous communityINE 2004–2018
Government expenditureFinal government consumption. Data in 2010 constant eurosMinistry of Finance and Public Office (Ministerio de Hacienda y Función Pública) 2004–2018

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix

VariableMeanStd. dev.1234567
1GDP5.6E+076.0E+071
2TEA5.5973.9950.1321
3R&D staff in Public Administration2250.7903592.5640.9130.0791
4Researchers in Public Administration1218.9211866.6490.9320.0840.9911
5Education31.2307.1070.293−0.0490.3200.2951
6Firms171999.700174904.9000.9830.1320.8510.8800.1801
7Self-employees in industry977.3131944.2990.4930.1180.3830.453− 0.0610.5231
8Self-employees in construction2687.3636045.7400.4460.1260.4100.469−0.0810.4650.928
9Self-employees in service10373.95018745.8100.6820.1170.6820.7270.0910.6740.855
10Public administration expenditure in R&D137098.300231125.8000.8980.0740.9940.9800.3380.8260.354
11Unemployment rate16.7537.611−0.0310.1430.0330.0070.2760.0090.354
12GDP per capita22253.2704494.0290.3990.0450.4470.4460.7810.2750.177
13Population2446.2642401.7900.9470.1270.7930.8150.1230.9830.466
14R&D expenditure0.9580.5210.5430.0570.5130.5130.7490.4760.273
15Capital12,600,00013,000,0000.9530.1420.8510.8830.1650.9560.652
16Labor force1032.4311040.7580.9810.1370.8650.8930.1830.9940.570
17Government expenditure9,479,5198,762,5500.9190.1050.7420.7680.1290.9520.367
Variable8910111213141516
8Self-employees in construction1
9Self-employees in service0.9161
10Public administration expenditure in R&D0.3740.6531
11Unemployment rate−0.360−0.2290.0231
12GDP per capita0.1680.3160.474−0.4781
13Population0.4150.6120.7630.0790.1661
14R&D expenditure0.2310.3930.520−0.3470.7210.4301
15Capital0.6250.7730.832−0.1490.3270.9250.4931
16Labor force0.5240.7210.839−0.0340.2910.9760.4950.9731
17Government expenditure0.3000.5120.7180.1760.1480.9710.4080.8710.935

Note(s): Italic coefficients are significant at 10%

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Main results

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
Equation 1Ln TEALn TEALn TEALn TEALn TEALn TEALn TEA
Ln R&D staff in Public Administration (t−1) 0.114** 0.123*
(0.049) (0.064)
Ln Researchers in Public Administration (t−1) 0.102+ 0.140**
(0.062) (0.070)
Ln Education (t−1)−0.038***−0.040***−0.039*** −0.040***−0.043***−0.045***
(0.012)(0.011)(0.011) (0.007)(0.008)(0.008)
Ln number of firms (t−1)−1.063***−1.294***−1.231*** −0.688*−0.990**−1.074***
(0.374)(0.358)(0.360) (0.380)(0.406)(0.401)
Ln Self-employees in industry (t−1)−0.056−0.060−0.062 −0.061−0.074+−0.087*
(0.045)(0.045)(0.044) (0.046)(0.046)(0.046)
Ln Self-employees in construction (t−1)0.0890.1090.077 −0.119**−0.099*−0.106**
(0.082)(0.082)(0.080) (0.052)(0.053)(0.053)
Ln Self-employees in service (t−1)−0.160*−0.180**−0.139* 0.139*0.1150.129*
(0.084)(0.078)(0.080) (0.074)(0.074)(0.077)
Ln Public administration expenditure in R&D (t−1)0.035−0.026−0.019 0.006−0.054−0.059
(0.030)(0.031)(0.030) (0.031)(0.043)(0.040)
Ln unemployment rate (t−1)−0.157−0.124−0.113 −0.500***−0.517***−0.533***
(0.162)(0.168)(0.174) (0.080)(0.079)(0.079)
Ln GDP per capita (t−1)1.449***1.576***1.512*** 0.881***1.050***1.073***
(0.490)(0.473)(0.489) (0.333)(0.340)(0.332)
Ln population (t−1)1.274***1.443***1.374*** 0.859**1.107***1.181***
(0.467)(0.449)(0.452) (0.398)(0.413)(0.408)
Constant−7.509**−7.414**−7.145* −3.058−2.938−2.640
(3.468)(3.469)(3.679) (2.335)(2.318)(2.366)
R2 0.418 0.428 0.429 0.277 0.289 0.297
Equation 2 Ln GDP Ln GDP Ln GDP Ln GDP Ln GDP Ln GDP Ln GDP
Ln TEA (t−1) 0.012**0.013***0.013***0.013***
(0.006)(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Ln R&D expenditure (t−1) −0.007−0.008−0.008−0.006
(0.020)(0.019)(0.019)(0.019)
Ln capital (t−1) 0.072***0.070***0.070***0.068***
(0.014)(0.011)(0.011)(0.011)
Ln labor force (t−1) 0.260***0.252***0.251***0.237***
(0.057)(0.049)(0.049)(0.049)
Ln government expenditure (t−1) 0.119***0.117***0.117***0.115***
(0.029)(0.026)(0.026)(0.025)
Constant 10.998***11.068***11.068***11.183***
(0.376)(0.317)(0.317)(0.320)
Observations231231229229221221220
Regional fixed-effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed-effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
R2 0.9250.9310.9590.912
AIC111.741110.053108.998−1089.256−908.881−910.522−912.599
BIC184.031185.786184.539−972.509−759.362−757.605−759.886

Note(s): *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1, + p = 0.1. Standard errors in parentheses

Source(s): Authors' own creation

Descriptive statistics by autonomous community and city

Community/CityGDPaTEAbR&D staff in public administrationcResearchers in public administrationc
Andalucía1.43E+086.2375,272.4332709.327
Aragón3.28E+075.1841175.093639.133
Principado de Asturias2.17E+073.568559.500269.806
Illes Balears2.69E+076.196455.553311.666
Canarias4.04E+075.4891166.953670.773
Cantabria1.24E+075.474377.220240.086
Castilla - León5.34E+079.096913.880466.853
Castilla - La Mancha3.71E+075.931466.446292.684
Catalunya1.99E+086.9888390.2935092.660
Comunitat Valenciana9.96E+075.3242426.7471444.807
Extremadura1.75E+075.937485.553199.406
Galicia5.52E+075.1381440.677758.500
Comunidad de Madrid1.96E+086.31213809.3106798.933
Región de Murcia2.74E+075.556632.721360.192
Comunidad Foral de Navarra1.77E+074.967341.957244.757
País Vasco6.35E+074.4901028.720598.16
La Rioja7,748,9455.092238.980128.973
Ceuta1,538,7243.8701.3000.700
Melilla1,394,0664.1721.3000.700

Note(s): aINE (Instituto Nacional de Estadística): https://www.ine.es

b GEM (Global Entrepreneurship Monitor): https://www.gemconsortium.org

c Ministry of Economics, Industry, and Competitiveness: https://datos.gob.es/es/

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Results using 2SLS

(1)(2)(3)
Equation (1)Ln TEALn TEALn TEA
Ln R&D staff in Public Administration (t−1) 0.122*
(0.065)
Ln Researchers in Public Administration (t−1) 0.138*
(0.072)
Ln Education (t−1)−0.040***−0.043***−0.044***
(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)
Ln number of firms (t−1)−0.695*−0.985**−1.049**
(0.389)(0.416)(0.412)
Ln Self-employees in industry (t−1)−0.062−0.074−0.086*
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)
Ln Self-employees in construction (t−1)−0.118**−0.099*−0.107**
(0.054)(0.054)(0.054)
Ln Self-employees in service (t−1)0.139*0.1150.132*
(0.075)(0.076)(0.079)
Ln Public administration expenditure in R&D (t−1)0.006−0.054−0.057
(0.031)(0.044)(0.041)
Ln unemployment rate (t−1)−0.501***−0.517***−0.530***
(0.082)(0.081)(0.081)
Ln GDP per capita (t−1)0.890***1.045***1.046***
(0.340)(0.348)(0.341)
Ln population (t−1)0.867**1.102***1.153***
(0.408)(0.424)(0.419)
Constant−3.110−2.913−2.499
(2.390)(2.378)(2.427)
R20.2770.2890.297
Equation (2)Ln GDPLn GDPLn GDP
Ln TEA (t−1)0.013**0.013**0.013**
(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Ln R&D expenditure (t−1)−0.008−0.008−0.005
(0.020)(0.020)(0.020)
Ln capital (t−1)0.070***0.070***0.068***
(0.012)(0.012)(0.012)
Ln labor force (t−1)0.251***0.251***0.239***
(0.053)(0.053)(0.053)
Ln government expenditure (t−1)0.117***0.117***0.115***
(0.028)(0.028)(0.028)
Constant11.068***11.068***11.181***
(0.345)(0.345)(0.348)
Observations221221220
Regional fixed-effectsYesYesYes
Year fixed-effectsYesYesYes
R20.9310.9590.912

Note(s): *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Standard errors in parentheses

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Results using self-employment as a proxy for entrepreneurship

(1)(2)(3)
Equation (1)Ln self-employmentLn self-employmentLn self-employment
Ln R&D staff in Public Administration (t−1) 0.056***
(0.021)
Ln Researchers in Public Administration (t−1) 0.025
(0.025)
Ln Education (t−1)0.010***0.008***0.009***
(0.003)(0.003)(0.003)
Ln number of firms (t−1)0.675***0.528***0.608***
(0.124)(0.133)(0.135)
Ln Public administration expenditure in R&D (t−1)0.021*−0.0080.009
(0.011)(0.015)(0.014)
Ln unemployment rate (t−1)−0.245***−0.252***−0.247***
(0.027)(0.027)(0.027)
Ln GDP per capita (t−1)−1.071***−0.975***−1.036***
(0.107)(0.111)(0.113)
Ln population (t−1)0.281**0.405***0.337**
(0.129)(0.135)(0.137)
Constant12.484***12.410***12.540***
(0.751)(0.740)(0.783)
R20.9870.9880.986
Equation (2)Ln GDPLn GDPLn GDP
Ln self-employment (t−1)0.085*0.088**0.068
(0.045)(0.045)(0.045)
Ln R&D expenditure (t−1)−0.007−0.007−0.007
(0.015)(0.015)(0.014)
Ln capital (t−1)0.067***0.067***0.066***
(0.011)(0.011)(0.010)
Ln labor force (t−1)0.226***0.225***0.223***
(0.051)(0.051)(0.051)
Ln government expenditure (t−1)0.119***0.119***0.118***
(0.023)(0.023)(0.023)
Constant10.554***10.536***10.727***
(0.407)(0.407)(0.414)
Observations238238236
Regional fixed-effectsYesYesYes
Year fixed-effectsYesYesYes
R20.9310.9590.912

Note(s): *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Standard errors in parentheses

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Appendix 1

Table A1

Appendix 2

Table A2

Appendix 3

Table A3

References

Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B. and Lehmann, E.E. (2013), “The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 757-774.

Acs, Z.J., Braunerhjelm, P., Audretsch, D.B. and Carlsson, B. (2009), “The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 15-30.

Acs, Z., Desai, S. and Klapper, L.F. (2008), “What does ‘entrepreneurship’ data really show?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 265-281.

Amorós, J.E., Ciravegna, L., Mandakovic, V. and Stenholm, P. (2019a), “Necessity or opportunity? The effects of state fragility and economic development on entepreneurial effects”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 43 No. 4, pp. 725-750.

Amorós, J.E., Poblete, C. and Mandakovic, V. (2019b), “R&D transfer, policy and innovative ambitious entrepreneurship: evidence from Latin American countries”, Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 44 No. 5, pp. 1396-1415.

Aparicio, S., Audretsch, D. and Urbano, D. (2022a), “Governmental Support for enterpreneurship in Spain: an institutional approach”, Hacienda Pública Española/Review of Public Economics, Nos 243-(4/2022), pp. 29-49.

Aparicio, S., Audretsch, D., Noguera, M. and Urbano, D. (2022b), “Can female entrepreneurs boost social mobility in developing countries? An institutional analysis”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 175, 121401.

Aparicio, S., Urbano, D. and Audretsch, D. (2016), “Institutional factors, opportunity entrepreneurship and economic growth: panel data evidence”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 102, pp. 45-61.

Aparicio, S., Urbano, D. and Stenholm, P. (2021), “Attracting the enterpreneurial potential: a multilevel institutional approach”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 168, 120748.

Arenas, L., Atienza, M. and Vergara Perucich, J.F. (2020), “Ruta N, an island of innovation in Medellín’s downtown”, Local Economy, Vol. 35 No. 5, pp. 419-439.

Arin, K.P., Huang, V.Z., Minniti, M., Nandialath, A.M. and Reich, O.F. (2015), “Revisiting the determinants of entrepreneurship: a Bayesian approach”, Journal of Management, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 607-631.

Arshed, N., Carter, S. and Mason, C. (2014), “The ineffectiveness of entrepreneurship policy: is policy formulation to blame?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 639-659.

Audretsch, D.B. (2007), The Enterpreneurial Society, Oxford University Press, New York.

Audretsch, D. (2012), “Entrepreneurship research”, Management Decision, Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 755-764.

Audretsch, D.B. (2021), “Have we oversold the Silicon Valley model of entrepreneurship?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 56 No. 2, pp. 849-856.

Audretsch, D.B. and Belitski, M. (2022), “A strategic alignment framework for the entrepreneurial university”, Industry and Innovation, Vol. 29 No. 2, pp. 285-309.

Audretsch, D. B.and Keilbach, M. (2008), “Resolving the knowledge paradox: knowledge-spillover entrepreneurship and economic growth”, Research Policy, Vol. 37 No. 10, pp. 1697-1705.

Audretsch, D. B.and Link, A.N. (2019), “Entrepreneurship and knowledge spillovers from the public sector”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp. 195-208.

Audretsch, D.B., Link, A.N. and van Hasselt, M. (2019), “Knowledge begets knowledge: university knowledge spillovers and the output of scientific papers from U.S. Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) projects”, Scientometrics, Vol. 121, pp. 1367-1383.

Audretsch, D.B., Siegel, D.S. and Terjesen, S. (2020), “Entrepreneurship in the public and nonprofit sectors”, Public Administration Review, Vol. 80 No. 3, pp. 468-472.

Bacq, S., Hertel, C. and Lumpkin, G.T. (2022), “Communities at the nexus of entrepreneurship and societal impact: a cross-disciplinary literature review”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 37 No. 5, 106231.

Bailey, J.B. and Thomas, D.W. (2017), “Regulating away competition: the effect of regulation on entrepreneurship and employment”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, Vol. 52 No. 3, pp. 237-254.

Baumol, W.J. (1990), “Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive”, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 No. 5, pp. 893-921.

Bennett, D.L. (2019), “Infrastructure investments and entrepreneurial dynamism in the US”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 34 No. 5, 105907.

Berrill, J., O’Hagan-Luff, M. and van Stel, A. (2020), “The moderating role of education in the relationship between FDI and entrepreneurial activity”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 54 No. 4, pp. 1041-1059.

Bjørnskov, C. and Foss, N.J. (2016), “Vol. Institutions, entrepreneurship, and economic growth: what do we know and what do we still need to know?”, The Academy of Management Perspectives, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 292-315.

Bosma, N. (2013), “The Global entrepreneurship monitor (GEM) and its impact on entrepreneurship research”, Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 143-248.

Bosma, N., Sanders, M. and Stam, E. (2018), “Institutions, entrepreneurship, and economic growth in Europe”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 51 No. 2, pp. 483-499.

Brush, C.G. Duhaime, I.M., Gartner, W.B., Stewart, A., Katz, J. A. Hitt, M.A., Alvarez, S.A., Meyer, G.D. and Venkataraman, S. (2003), “Doctoral education in the field of entrepreneurship”, Journal of Management, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 309-331.

Bruton, G.D., Ahlstrom, D. and Li, H.L. (2010), “Institutional theory and entrepreneurship: where are we now and where do we need to move in the future?”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 421-440.

Carree, M.A. and Thurik, A.R. (2008), “The lag structure of the impact of business ownership on economic performance in OECD countries”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 101-110.

Carree, M., van Stel, A., Thurik, R. and Wennekers, S. (2002), “Economic development and business ownership: an analysis using data of 23 OECD countries in the period 1976–1996”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 271-290.

Carree, M., van Stel, A., Thurik, R. and Wennekers, S. (2007), “The relationship between economic development and business ownership revisited”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 281-291.

Chowdhury, F., Audretsch, D.B. and Belitski, M. (2019), “Institutions and entrepreneurship quality”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 43 No. 1, pp. 51-81.

Civera, J.N., , M P.and López-Muñoz, J.F. (2021), “Do contextual factors influence entrepreneurship? Spain’s regional evidences”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 105-129.

Culkin, N. (2016), “Entrepreneurial universities in the region: the force awakens?”, International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp. 4-16.

Dau, L.A. and Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2014), “To formalize or not to formalize: entrepreneurship and premarket institutions”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 29 No. 5, pp. 668-686.

Del Rey, E. and Lopez-Garcia, M.A. (2020), “On government-created credit markets for education and endogenous growth”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 92, pp. 170-179.

Demircioglu, M.A. and Audretsch, D.B. (2019), “Public sector innovation: the effect of universities”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 596-614.

Demircioglu, M.A. and Chowdhury, F. (2021), “Entrepreneurship in public organizations: the role of leadership behavior”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 57 No. 3, pp. 1107-1123.

Dencker, J.C., Bacq, S., Gruber, M. and Haas, M. (2019), “Reconceptualizing necessity entrepreneurship: a contextualized framework of entrepreneurial processes under the condition of basic needs”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 60-79.

Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Salines, F. and Shleifer, A. (2002), “The regulation of entry”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 No. 1, pp. 1-37.

Dyer, J.H. and Singh, H. (1998), “The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 660-679.

Erken, H., Donselaar, P. and Thurik, R. (2018), “Total factor productivity and the role of entrepreneurship”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 43 No. 6, pp. 1493-1521.

Estrin, S., Korosteleva, J. and Mickiewicz, T. (2022), “Schumpeterian entry: innovation, experting, and growth aspirations of entrepreneurs”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 46 No. 2, pp. 269-296.

Etzkowitz, H. (2017), “Innovation Lodestar: the entrepreneurial university in a stellar knowledge firmament”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 123, pp. 122-129.

Fernandes, C.I., Veiga, P.M., Ferreira, J.J. and Hughes, M. (2021), “Green growth versus economic growth: do sustainable technology transfer and innovations lead to an imperfect choice?”, Business Strategy and the Environment, Vol. 30 No. 4, pp. 2021-2037.

Ferreira, J.J., Fayolle, A., Fernandes, C. and Raposo, M. (2017), “Effects of Schumpeterian and Kirznerian entrepreneurship on economic growth: panel data evidence”, Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, Vol. 29 Nos 1-2, pp. 27-50.

Foss, N.J., Klein, P.G. and Bjørnskov, C. (2019), “The context of entrepreneurial judgment: organizations, markets, and institutions”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 56 No. 6, pp. 1197-1213.

González-Pernía, J.L. and Peña-Legazkue, I. (2015), “Export-oriented entrepreneurship and regional economic growth”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 45 No. 3, pp. 505-522.

González-Pernía, J.L., Guerrero, M., Jung, A. and Pena-Legazkue (2018), “Economic recession shake-out and entrepreneurship: evidence from Spain”, BRQ Business Research Quarterly, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 153-167.

Gries, T. and Naudé, W. (2010), “Entrepreneurship and structural economic transformation”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 34 No. 1, pp. 13-29.

Gumbau Albert, M. (2017), “Entrepreneurship, innovation and regional performance: application for the Spanish regions”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 29 Nos 3-4, pp. 271-291.

Hausmann, R. (2016), “Economic development and the accumulation of know-how”, Welsh Economic Review, Vol. 24, pp. 13-16.

Hessels, J., Van Gelderen, M. and Thurik, R. (2008), “Entrepreneurial aspirations, motivations, and their drivers”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 31 No. 3, pp. 323-339.

Hofstede, G. (2005), Culture and Organizations: Software of the mind, 2nd Revised and expanded edition, McGraw-Hill, New York.

Hsieh, F.Y., Lavori, P.W., Cohen, H.J. and Feussner, J.R. (2003), “An overview of VIFs for sample-size calculation”, Evaluation and the Health Professions, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 239-257.

Hughes, M., Hughes, P., Hodgkinson, I., Chang, Y. Y.and Chang, C. Y.(2021), “Knowledge‐based theory, entrepreneurial orientation, stakeholder engagement, and firm performance”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Online first, doi: 10.1002/sej.1409.

Inglehart, R. (1990), Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Society, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Iversen, J., Jørgensen, R. and Malchow-Møller, N. (2007), “Defining and measuring entrepreneurship”, Foundations and Trends® in Entrepreneurship, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 1-63.

Klein, P.G., Mahoney, J.T., McGahan, A.M. and Pitelis, C.N. (2010), “Toward a theory of public entrepreneurship”, European Management Review, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 1-15.

Klofsten, M., Fayolle, A., Guerrero, M., Mian, S., Urbano, D. and Wright, M. (2019), “The entrepreneurial university as driver for economic growth and social change – key strategic challenges”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 141, pp. 149-158.

Kraus, S., McDowell, W., Ribeiro-Soriano, D.E. and Rodríguez-García, M. (2021), “The role of innovation and knowledge for entrepreneurship and regional development”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 33 Nos 3-4, pp. 175-184.

Landström, H. (2020), “The evolution of entrepreneurship as a scholarly field”, Foundations and Trends® in Entrepreneurship, Vol. 16 No. 2, pp. 65-243.

Liñán, F. and Fernandez-Serrano, J. (2014), “National culture, entrepreneurship and economic development: different patterns across the European Union”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 42 No. 4, pp. 685-701.

Liñán, F., Urbano, D. and Guerrero, M. (2011), “Regional variations in entrepreneurial cognitions: start-up intentions of university students in Spain”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 23 Nos 3-4, pp. 187-215.

Link, A.N. (2021), “Knowledge transfers from federally funded research and development centers”, Science and Public Policy, Vol. 48 No. 4, pp. 576-581.

Link, A.N. and Scott, J.T. (2021), “Scientific publications at US federal research laboratories”, Scientometrics. doi: 10.1007/s11192-020-03854-2.

Link, A.N. and Wright, M. (2015), “On the failure of RandD projects”, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, Vol. 62 No. 4, pp. 442-448.

Margolis, D.N. (2014), “By choice and by necessity: entrepreneurship and self-employment in the developing world”, The European Journal of Development Research, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 419-436.

McMullen, J.S., Bagby, D.R. and Palich, L.E. (2008), “Economic freedom and the motivation to engage in entrepreneurial action”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 32 No. 5, pp. 875-895.

Mickiewicz, T., Stephan, U. and Shami, M. (2021), “The consequences of short‐term institutional change in the rule of law for entrepreneurship”, Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 11 No. 4, pp. 709-739.

Muñoz-Mora, J.C., Aparicio, S., Martinez-Moya, D. and Urbano, D. (2022), “From immigrants to local entrepreneurs: understanding the effects of migration on entrepreneurship in a highly informal country”, International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research, Vol. 28 No. 9, pp. 78-103.

North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

North, D.C. (2005), Understanding the Progress of Economic Change, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Olcay, G.A. and Bulu, M. (2017), “Is measuring the knowledge creation of universities possible?: A review of university rankings”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol. 123, pp. 153-160.

Pahnke, A. and Welter, F. (2019), “The German Mittelstand: antithesis to Silicon valley entrepreneurship?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 52 No. 2, pp. 345-358.

Peña-Legazkue, I., Guerrero, M., González-Pernía, J.L. and Montero, J. (2018), Global Entrepreneurship Monitor: Informe GEM España 2017-2018, Editorial de la Universidad de Cantabria, Santander.

Peña-Legazkue, I., Guerrero, M., González-Pernía, J.L. and Montero, J. (2020), Global Entrepreneurship Monitor: Informe GEM España 2019-2020, Editorial de la Universidad de Cantabria, Santander.

Peters, M.A. and Besley, T. (2008), “Academic entrepreneurship and the creative economy”, Thesis Eleven, Vol. 94 No. 1, pp. 88-105.

Pinzón, N., Montero, J. and González-Pernía, J.L. (2021), “The influence of individual characteristics on getting involved in an entrepreneurial team: the contingent role of individualism”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal. doi: 10.1007/s11365-021-00768-0.

Pocek, J., Politis, D. and Gabrielsson, J. (2022), “Entrepreneurial learning in extra-curricular start-up programs for students”, International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research, Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 325-345.

Puente, R., González Espitia, C.G. and Cervilla, M.A. (2019), “Necessity entrepreneurship in Latin America: it’s not that simple”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 31 Nos 9-10, pp. 953-983.

Scott, W.R. (1995), Institutions and Organizations: Ideas and Interests, Sage, Thousand Oak, CA.

Smallbone, D. (2016), “Entrepreneurship policy: issues and challenges”, Small Enterprise Research, Vol. 23 No. 3, pp. 201-218.

Spigel, B. and Vinodrai, T. (2021), “Meeting its Waterloo? Recycling in entrepreneurial ecosystems after anchor firm collapse”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 33 Nos 7-8, pp. 599-620.

Stam, E. (2015), “Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique”, European Planning Studies, Vol. 23 No. 9, pp. 1759-1769.

Sutter, C., Bruton, G.D. and Chen, J. (2019), “Entrepreneurship as a solution to extreme poverty: a review and future research directions”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 34 No. 1, pp. 197-214.

Takata, M., Nakagawa, K., Yoshida, M., Matsuyuki, T., Matsuhashi, T., Kato, K. and Stevens, A.J. (2022), “Nurturing entrepreneurs: how do technology transfer professionals bridge the Valley of Death in Japan?”, Technovation, Vol. 109, 102161.

Teece, D.J., Pisano, G. and Shuen, A. (1997), “Dynamic capabilities and strategic management”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18 No. 7, pp. 509-533.

Terjesen, S. (2016), “The right stuff: a NASA technology-based new venture and the search for markets on earth”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 40 No. 3, pp. 713-726.

Urbano, D., Aparicio, S. and Audretsch, D. (2019), “Twenty-five years of research on institutions, entrepreneurship, and economic growth: what has been learned?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 53 No. 1, pp. 21-49.

Urbano, D., Audretsch, D., Aparicio, S. and Noguera, M. (2020), “Does entrepreneurial activity matter for economic growth in developing countries? The role of the institutional environment”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Vol. 16 No. 3, pp. 1065-1099.

van Gelderen, M., Wiklund, J. and McMullen, J.S. (2021), “Entrepreneurship in the future: A Delphi study of ETP and JBV editorial board members”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 45 No. 5, pp. 1239-1275.

van Stel, A. and van der Zwan, P. (2020), “Analyzing the changing education distributions of solo self-employed workers and employer entrepreneurs in Europe”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 55 No. 2, pp. 429-445.

van Stel, A., Storey, D.J. and Thurik, A.R. (2007), “The effect of business regulations on nascent and young business entrepreneurship”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 28 Nos 2-3, pp. 171-186.

Veciana, J.M. and Urbano, D. (2008), “The institutional approach to entrepreneurship research. Introduction”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Vol. 4 No. 4, pp. 365-379.

Voigt, S. (2013), “How (not) to measure institutions”, Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 1-26.

Voigt, S. (2018), “How to measure informal institutions”, Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 14 No. 1, pp. 1-22.

Wennekers, S., van Stel, A., Thurik, R. and Reynolds, P. (2005), “Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic development”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 293-309.

Williamson, O.E. (2000), “The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 595-613.

Wong, P.K., Ho, Y.P. and Autio, E. (2005), “Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: evidence from GEM data”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 335-350.

Wong, P.K., Ho, Y.P. and Singh, A. (2007), “Towards an ‘entrepreneurial university’ model to support knowledge-based economic development: the case of the national University of Singapore”, World Development, Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 941-958.

Zellner, A. and Theil, H. (1962), “Three-stage least squares: simultaneous estimation of simultaneous equations”, Econometrica, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 54-78.

Zhai, Q., Su, J., Ye, M. and Xu, Y. (2019), “How do institutions relate to entrepreneurship: an integrative model”, Entrepreneurship Research Journal, Vol. 9 No. 2, 20170001.

Acknowledgements

Sebastian Aparicio as a Serra Hunter Fellow acknowledges the Serra Hunter Programme and the Catalan government for constant support. Additionally, Sebastian acknowledges COLCIENCIAS Ph.D. programme (617/2013), as well as Sapiencia-Enlaza Mundos (Municipio de Medellín) for financial support during Ph.D. studies. Mat Hughes acknowledges support from the School of Business at the University of Leicester. Likewise, David Audretsch thanks the Paul H. O’Neill School of Public and Environmental Affairs (SPEA) at Indiana University for constant support. Finally, David Urbano acknowledges the financial support from project ECO2017-87885-P (Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness), 2017-SGR-1056 (Economy and Knowledge Department, Catalan Government), and ICREA under ICREA Academia programme.

Corresponding author

David Urbano is the corresponding author and can be contacted at: david.urbano@uab.cat

About the authors

Sebastian Aparicio is a Serra Hunter Fellow and a Researcher of the Centre for Entrepreneurship and Social Innovation Research (CREIS) at the Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB). He is also affiliated as a Research Fellow in the Centre for University Entrepreneurship (CIEU-UAB–), as a Junior Research Fellow in the Institute for Development Strategies at the School of Public and Environmental Affairs (IDS-SPEA, Indiana University) and a Researcher at Fundación ECSIM (Colombia). His research focuses on the effects of entrepreneurship on economic development under the institutional lenses. Some of his research has been published in various international journals, such as Journal of World Business, Technological Forecasting and Social Change and Small Business Economics.

Mathew (Mat) Hughes is Schulze Distinguished Professor and Professor of Innovation and Entrepreneurship in the School of Business at the University of Leicester. His research interests lie at the intersection of entrepreneurship and strategy and include entrepreneurial orientation, social capital, organizational ambidexterity and innovation, across a variety of organizational contexts. Mat has published in such premier-refereed journals such as Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, British Journal of Management and Journal of World Business. He is an Associate Editor of the Journal of Family Business Strategy. Moreover, Mat is a member of the editorial review boards of Journal of Management Studies, Journal of Business Venturing, British Journal of Management, New England Journal of Entrepreneurship and International Journal of Entrepreneurial Venturing.

David Audretsch is a Distinguished Professor and the Ameritech Chair of Economic Development in the Paul H. O’Neill School of Public and Environmental Affairs (SPEA) at Indiana University. He is also the Director of the Institute for Development Strategies (IDS) at SPEA. David is the co-founder and co-editor of Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal; as well as a member of the Editorial Board and guest editor of several journals in entrepreneurship, management and economics. He was awarded the 2001 Global Award for Entrepreneurship Research by the FSF, and in 2011 he received the Schumpeter Prize from the University of Wuppertal. He has several scholarly international publications analyzing the links between entrepreneurship, government policy, innovation, economic development and global competitiveness.

David Urbano is Professor of Entrepreneurship at the Department of Business, Director at the Centre for Entrepreneurship and Social Innovation Research (CREIS) (Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona) and ICREA-Academia research fellow. His research focuses on the analysis of factors affecting entrepreneurship in different contexts, using institutional economics as a theoretical framework and combining quantitative and qualitative methodologies. He has several scholarly international publications and participates in numerous international research projects (e.g. GEM, PSED and GUESSS). He is a research fellow at IfM Bonn (Germany) and at the Basque Observatory for Entrepreneurship (OVE-EBB), visiting professor at Trinity Business School (Trinity College Dublin) and regularly visits Haas School of Business (University of California Berkeley).

Related articles