Does wage bonus positively impact the economy?

Cuong Le-Van (Paris School of Economics, Paris, France) (TIMAS, Thang Long University, Hanoi, Vietnam)
Nguyen To-The (VNU University of Economics and Business, Vietnam National University, Hanoi, Vietnam)

Fulbright Review of Economics and Policy

ISSN: 2635-0173

Article publication date: 6 July 2021

Issue publication date: 31 August 2021

1047

Abstract

Purpose

Total factor productivity (TFP), for a country and for a firm as well, is a crucial element for economic growth by inducing high output. Actually, workers' effort is among the important factors that positively influence the TFP.

Design/methodology/approach

In this paper, the authors assume that the wage bonus enhances the worker's effort. Wage bonus is an incentive mechanism and plays a role in the TFP as is shown in a recent paper by Le Van and Pham (2021). The firm will maximize its profits. The supplies of capital and workers are exogenous. At equilibrium, the authors obtain that wage bonus has positive effects on output, labor productivity and price of the output.

Findings

The wage bonus system can make the optimal sequence of outputs grow without bounds. And if the optimal sequence converges to a steady state, this one can be characterized by higher output per capita than that in the steady state without the bonus.

Originality/value

In particular, the result show if, thanks to the wage bonus externality effect, the production may become of increasing returns and if the incentive mechanism is very strong, any optimal path of physical capitals will converge to infinity.

Keywords

Citation

Le-Van, C. and To-The, N. (2021), "Does wage bonus positively impact the economy?", Fulbright Review of Economics and Policy, Vol. 1 No. 1, pp. 21-31. https://doi.org/10.1108/FREP-02-2021-0016

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Cuong Le-Van and Nguyen To-The

License

Published in Fulbright Review of Economics and Policy. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) license. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this license may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Productivity is a key concept in economics. It is crucial for economic growth since it induces high output of the firms. Let us recall that the total factor productivity (TFP) is the portion of growth, which is not explained by growth in inputs used in the production process. The TFP measures the efficiency with which factor inputs are combined and often used to proxy technological progress.

Estimating contribution to growth of different factors is not an easy task [1]. Looking back to history, Solow (1957) estimated that TFP growth accounted for 87.5% of growth in output per worker of the United States over the period 1909–1949 [2]. Similarly and more recently, Zhu (2012) estimated that the growth contribution of TFP growth is 78% of the growth in gross domestic product (GDP) per capita of China during 1978–2007.

In this paper, we propose to introduce an incentive mechanism by a wage bonus system. A firm announces a bonus which is proportional to real wage. The workers anticipate a real wage and improve their effort. At equilibrium, where anticipated wage equals equilibrium wage, we obtain that the wage bonus system improves the output of firm, the real income per capita of the workers, the labor productivity and the competitiveness [3] of the firm as well. Moreover, the output per capita may increase without bound or converges to a steady state, which is larger than the one without a wage bonus system.

Our paper is in the stream of efficiency wages. Efficiency wage, which was introduced by Marshall (1890), would make employers pay different wages to workers who are of different efficiencies. Later, the use of the term is quite different and refers to the idea that higher wages may increase the productivity of the workers. For Leibenstein (1957), the wage–productivity relationship should be broken in two parts: (1) the relation between income and nutrition and (2) the relation between nutrition and productivity. Several theories try to explain why managers pay efficiency wages. For instance, since it is difficult to measure the quantity and the quality of the effort of the worker, and since this one may shirk by doing less work than agreed, the managers pay efficiency wages in order to increase or create the cost of job loss (see, for instance, Shapiro & Stiglitz, 1984). In Solow (1979), wage enters the short-run production function. A firm can minimize the cost by letting its wage offer unchanged if wage enters the production function in a labor augmenting way. Solow (1979) explains why wage may be sticky. Combining efficiency wage theory and public service motivation, Taylor & Taylor (2011) build a model to examine empirically the relationship between wages and public service motivation for 15 countries.

The remaining of the study is organized as follows. In Section 2, we recall the definition of TFP and give the several factors constituting the TFP. In Section 3, we define the wage bonus system. The economy is set in Section 4. The results are given in Section 5. In Section 6, we set an optimal growth model where, in presence of wage bonus system, the sequence of optimal outputs per capita may converge to infinity or converge to a steady state, which is larger than the one without a wage bonus system. In particular, we show if, thanks to the wage bonus externality effect, the production may become of increasing returns and if the incentive mechanism is very strong, any optimal path of physical capitals will converge to infinity. All the results are summarized in Section 7 which concludes.

2. Total factor productivity and economic growth

This study employed Solow (1957) to clarify the relationship between TFP and economic growth. In this paper, Solow used the data of the US economy of the 50 beginning years of the 20th century and ran a regression.

(1)Δln(Yt)=B+αΔln(Kt)+βΔln(Nt),
where Yt, Kt and Nt are, respectively, the GDP, physical capital and number of workers. Solow (1957) found that TFP growth accounted for 87.5% of growth in output per worker over that period.

We can see that this regression is derived from a production function (Cobb–Douglas function).

(2)Yt=AtKtαNtβ.

Obviously, B = Δ ln(At) in the regression [4]. B is called Solow residual while At is called technical progress or TFP. TFP is the portion of growth in output not explained by growth in traditionally measured inputs of labor and capital used in production. TFP is measured as the ratio of aggregate output (e.g. GDP) to aggregate inputs (here, when β = 1 − α, the quantity KαNβ represents aggregate inputs as a weighted product of inputs K and N). The rate of TFP growth is calculated by subtracting average growth rates of labor and capital inputs from the growth rate of output.

Furthermore, Le Van & Pham (2021) consider Harrod, Solow and Ramsey models to show that, for a closed economy, its growth depends crucially on the TFP. If the TFP is high then the economy takes off and grows without bound. If the TFP is low, the economy collapses [5].

They show that the TFP is not a blackbox. By referring to the concepts (knowledge, human capital and management) introduced by Romer (1986), Lucas (1988) and Bloom, Eifert, Mahajan, McKenzie & Roberts (2013), they propose a production function Y = AKαNβ where the TFP is A[amζα(θh)β], where a is a normalization constant, m is an indicator of the management quality, h is the human capital, ζ is the quality of the technology of the physical capital and θ is the workers effort. We assume θ depends positively on a bonus denoted by b (incentive mechanism). To summarize, we have the following production function.

(3)Y=AkαNβ
(4)with the TFP is A=amζα(θh)β

3. Wage bonus as an incentive mechanism

We define the wage bonus b by b = μω, where μ ⩾ 0 and ω is real wage [6]. The real earned income of a worker, I, will now be I = ω + b = (1 + μ)ω. For simplicity, we write θ(b)β = ɛ(μω). Since we focus on the effect of real wage bonus, we suppose, for convenience, that 1=amζαhβ. The production function (Eqn 3) now becomes

Y=ε(μω)KαN1α
Assumption

:

We assume the function ɛ has the form

(5) ε(μω)=1+λξ(μω)

The function ξ will be called the incentive mechanism function. It is strictly increasing, ξ(0) = 0, strictly concave, differentiable, limx+ξ(x)x=0. The parameter λ > 0 measures the intensity of the incentive mechanism.

Comments on assumption

  • (1)Assume ξ(0) = 0 means no bonus implies no incentive mechanism. The effort equals 1 in this case.

  • (2)The assumption limx+ξ(x)x=0 means the effort cannot expand widely. In particular, when there is a maximal value for the workers effort ξ(+)<+, this assumption is satisfied.

4. The economy

In our economy, there exists a firm which produces a good by using k machines and N workers. The production technology is given by

(6)Y=ε(μωe)KαN1α=[1+λξ(μωe)]KαN1α,
where ωe is the real wage anticipated by the workers.

The firm will maximize its profit

π=ε(μωe)KαN1α(ω+μωe)NrK,
where r is real capital cost. In this economy, there is an exogenous supply of workers N and an exogenous supply of physical capital K. Given ω, ωe, r, the demands of firm for capital Kd(ω, ωe, r) and for workers Nd(ω, ωe, r) are obtained by maximizing its profit.

4.1 Equilibrium

Equilibrium real wages, ω* and real capital cost r* are characterized by,

  • (1) ωe = ω*.

  • (2) Nd(ω*,ωe,r*)=N

  • (3) Kd(ω*,ωe,r*)=K

5. The results

The demands for capital and for workers satisfy.

ε(μωe)αr=KdNd1αε(μωe)(1α)ω+μωe=NdKdα

Therefore, the equilibrium real wages and real capital cost solve the system.

(7)ε(μω*)αr*=KN1α
(8)ε(μω*)(1α)ω*(1+μ)=NKα

To prove that Eqn (8) has a unique solution ω* > 0, we require the following result.

Claim 1.

The function, for x ⩾ 0, ψ(x)=ε(x)x is strictly decreasing. Moreover, ψ(0) = + , ψ( + ) = 0.

Proof. We have,

ψ(x)=ε(x)xε(x)x2=λξ(x)x1+λξ(x)x2=λxξ(x)ξ(x)1x2

Since ξ is strictly concave, differentiable, we have ξ(x) − ξ(0) > ′(x), and since ξ(0) = 0, we have ′(x) − ξ(x) < 0. Hence, ψ′(x) < 0, ∀x > 0. We have ψ(x)>1x for all x > 0. Hence, ψ(x) → +  when x → 0. Since ψ(x)=1+λξ(x)x, we have ψ(x) → 0 when x → + . □

Therefore, Eqn (8) gives a unique value for the equilibrium real wage ω*; by consequence, Eqn (7) gives a unique value for the equilibrium real capital cost r*.

Let ω̃ be the equilibrium real wage and r̃ be the equilibrium real capital cost when there is no bonus, i.e. μ = 0. We obtain,

(9)αr̃=KN1α
(10)(1α)ω̃=NKα

It follows from Eqns (8) and (10) that

(11)(1+μ)ω*ω̃=ε(μω*)>1

In other words, the real income per capita, with bonus, (1 + μ)ω*, is higher than the real income per capita without bonus ω̃.

Also, it follows from Eqns (7) and (9) that r*>r̃. To interpret this result, let q denote the price of the physical capital. In this case, r̃=qp̃ and r*=qp*, where p̃ and p* are, respectively, the prices of the output when there are no wage bonus. Suppose q is exogenous, we conclude that the price of the output is lower when there is wage bonus.

The output, in presence of the wage bonus, Y*=ε(μω*)KαN1α is larger than KαN1α which is the output Y~, when the firm does not propose wage bonus.

Finally, we observe that the labor productivity πL* with wage bonus is higher than the labor productivity π̃L without wage bonus. Indeed,

πL*=ε(μω*)KNα>π̃L=KNα
Remark 1.

We mention that with bonus, if the real income per capita (1 + μ)ω* is higher than the one without bonus ω̃, we do not necessarily have that ω*>ω̃. The following example is a counter example.

Suppose ξ(x) = xγ, 0 < γ < 1. In this case, we get

1+λμγω*γ(1+μ)ω*=1ω̃

It is easy to check that ω*>ω̃λ>1ω̃γμ1γ. That means ω*>ω̃ if, and only if, the intensity parameter of the incentive mechanism, λ is high. If λ<1ω̃γμ1γ then ω*<ω̃.

Remark 2.

We want to show that, at equilibrium, the bonus μω* is bounded above. Indeed, on the one hand, we have the relations.

ε(μω*)μω*>ε(μω*)(1+μ)ω*=1ω̃
which imply
1+λξ(μω*)>μω*ω̃
and, on the other hand, the function 1 + λξ(x) has a unique x¯, which depends on λ,ω̃, such that
1+λξ(x¯)=x¯ω̃1+λξ(x)>xω̃ if x<x¯1+λξ(x)<xω̃ if x>x¯

Hence, μω*<x¯(λ,ω̃).

6. Wage bonus and economic growth

In this section, we consider an infinite horizon closed economy where there exists a social planner who represents N identical consumers. The consumers are also firms and workers. They provide physical capital to the firm by using their savings. The supply of labor is exogenous and constant over time. It equals N. The social planner seeks an economic growth path of consumptions (Nct*)t0 and physical capitals (Kt+1*)t0 such that, along this growth path,

  • (1)firm uses the wage bonus system described in the sections above.

  • (2)firm maximizes the profit at each period.

  • (3)There is full employment of labor.

  • (4)At each period, the saving of the consumers is used to invest in physical capital which they sell to the firm.

  • (5)The social planner maximizes the intertemporal utilities of the consumers under the constraints that the consumptions and the savings equal their incomes. These ones are composed of the profit of the firm, the value of the physical capital they sell to the firm and their earned income (wage plus bonus).

  • (6)The income at period 0 of the consumers is K0αN1α.

Let St* denote the saving of the consumers. If rt*,ωt* denote the capital price and the wage at date t, since the production function is of constant returns to scale, the profit is null, and the constraint of the consumers, at any period t ⩾ 1 writes

Nct*+St*=rt*Kt*+(1+μ)ωt*N
and
Kt+1*=St*

Since [7] the profit is null, we have rt*Kt*+(1+μ)ωt*N=Yt* where Yt* is the output of firm which equals ε(μωt*)Kt*αN1α [8].

Since the firm maximizes its profit at each period, ωt* is obtained (see Section 5)

(12)ε(μωt*)(1α)ωt*(1+μ)=NKt*α

The constraints of the consumers are rewritten as follows:

(13)Nc0*+K1*=K0αN1αfort>0,Nct*+Kt+1*=εωt*Kt*NKt*αN1α

In the following, we will consider the capital per capita, the output per capita and the consumption per capita and define

kt*=Kt*N,yt*=Yt*N
and k0=K0N.

We then obtain the constraint of each consumer

c0*+k1*=k0αfort>0,ct*+kt+1*=εωt*(kt*)kt*α

We assume that each consumer has the same intertemporal utility function   ln(c0) + β ln(c1) + ⋯ + βt  ln(ct) + ….

The social planner now solves for each consumer the optimal growth model

max{(ct,kt+1),t0}t=0+βtln(ct),β(0,1)c0+k1=k0αfort>0,ct+kt+1=εωt*(kt)ktαF(kt)

Observe that the left hand side (LHS) of Eqn (12) is a decreasing function in ωt* and the right hand side (RHS) of Eqn (12) is also a decreasing function in Kt. Hence, ωt* is an increasing function in Kt. In particular, if Kt → 0 then ωt*0.

Since the function F is increasing, the optimal sequence of physical capitals (kt*)t1 is monotonic (see Amir, 1996).

We will show that the optimal path (kt*)t cannot converge to zero by using the Euler equation associated with this optimal growth model. The Euler equation writes, with (ct*)t optimal consumption path.

(14)For all t:ct+1*ct*=βμεμω*(kt+1*)ω*(kt+1*)kt+1*α+αεμω*(kt+1*)(kt+1*)α1>βαεμω*(kt+1*)(kt+1*)α1>βα(kt+1*)α1

since ɛ(.) > 1.

If the sequence (kt*)t converges to zero, then the sequence ct+1*ct*t will converge to infinity, since (kt+1*)α1+ . That implies there exists T such that for any t > T we have ct+1*>ct*>>cT*>0.

However, the budget constraint

ct*=F(kt*)kt+1*
implies that ct* converges to zero, since F(kt*)0 and kt+1*0: we get a contradiction.

Therefore, the sequence (kt*)t and the sequence of optimal outputs per capita yt*=F(kt*) either are increasing and may converge to infinity, i.e. grow without bound or converge to steady states y^=F(k^) with k^=limt+kt*.

Suppose that the optimal sequence (kt*)t converge to a steady state k^. Then the optimal consumptions ct* converge to a steady state c^>0.

From Euler Eqn (14), we have

(15)1=βμεμω*(k^)ω*(k^)k^α+αεμω*(k^)k^α1>βαεμω*(k^)k^α1

We now compare with the case where μ = 0 (no wage bonus). In this case, from Le Van & Dana (2003), the optimal sequence k̃t will converge to a steady state k¯ which satisfy

1=βαk¯α1

We see, from Eqn (15), that

k¯α1>εμω*(k^)k^α1k^>εμω*(k^)11αk¯>k¯
and for the output per capita
y^=εμω*(k^)k^α>y¯=k¯α

At the steady state, the country is better off with a wage bonus system than without a bonus system. We can summarize these results in the following proposition:

Proposition 1.

An optimal path (kt*)t1 either converges to infinity or converges to a steady state k^, which is larger the steady state k¯=(βα)11α corresponding to the no wage bonus system.

Recall that ɛ(μω) = 1 + λξ(μω). Under some additional assumptions, any optimal path (kt*)t1 converges to infinity.

Proposition 2.

Assume ξ(x) = xγ, γ ∈ (0, 1) and α + γ > 1. Then there exists λ¯ such that for any λ>λ¯, any optimal path (kt*)t1 converges to infinity.

Proof. Suppose an optimal path (kt*)t converges to a steady state k^. Then it must satisfy (15). But it also satisfies (12), i.e.

ε(μω*(k^))(1α)ω*(k^)(1+μ)=1k^α

Equivalently,

(16)1+λμγω*(k^)γω*(k^)×(1α)(1+μ)=1k^α

This implies

(17)λμγω*(k^)γ1×(1α)(1+μ)<1k^α
(18)λμγ(1α)(1+μ)k^α<ω*(k^)1γ
(19)ω*(k^)>λμγ(1α)(1+μ)11γk^α1γ

Observe that from Eqn (15), one gets

(20)1>βαλμγω*(k^)γk^α1

Combine Eqns (20) and (19) to obtain

(21)1>βαλμγ(1α)(1+μ)λμγγ1γk^α+γ11γ1>βαμγ(1α)(1+μ)μγγ1γλ11γk^α+γ11γ

Let νβαμγ(1α)(1+μ)μγγ1γ. Then Eqn (21) rewrites as

(22)1>νλ11γk^α+γ11γk^<νγ1α+γ1λ1α+γ1

We see from Eqn (22) that, since α + γ > 1, if λ goes to infinity, then k^ goes to zero. Hence, there exists λ¯ such that, if λ>λ¯ then k^<k¯ (k¯=(βα)11α, in Proposition 1. That contradicts the statement in Proposition 1. Recall that any optimal path (kt*)t is monotonic and cannot converge to zero. Hence, any optimal (kt*)t converges to infinity. □

The interpretation of this result is as follows: if the production function becomes of increasing returns (α + γ > 1) and if the incentive parameter λ is high, then we have unbounded growth.

Remark 3.

Along the optimal path, at each period t, the capital price rt* is determined by the equation (see Section 5)

ε(μωt*)αrt*=Nkt*N1α=kt*1α
while the wage ωt* is given by
ε(μωt*)(1α)ωt*(1+μ)=NNkt*α=1kt*α

7. Conclusion

In our study, we obtain the following results,

  • (1)The real income per capita of the workers is higher with the wage bonus system;

  • (2)The output is also larger when the firm uses wage bonus as an incentive mechanism;

  • (3)If the price of the physical capital is exogenous, then the price of the output is lower in presence of the wage bonus system. This will be beneficial for the consumers and also for firm which becomes more competitive;

  • (4)Labor productivity improves with the wage bonus system;

  • (5)We set up an optimal growth model where in presence of the bonus system the optimal outputs per capita sequence may converge to infinity or converges to a steady state, which is higher than the one corresponding to the case without the wage bonus system and

  • (6)Moreover, if the production function becomes of increasing returns and if the incentive mechanism is high, then we have unbounded growth.

Notes

1.

See Hulten (2009) for a great treatment of growth accounting.

2.

Solow was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1987 for his contributions to the theory of economic growth. The paper Solow (1957) is an important part of these contributions.

3.

We say that a firm becomes more competitive if its output price diminishes

4.

The TFP At has constant rate of growth.

5.

The readers can also refer to Le Van & Dana (2003) for more details.

6.

In this paper, the bonus depends on wage. The wage bonus improves the economy in different ways. One can ask whether an “optimal” wage bonus exists or not. Consider the well-known efficiency wage which consists to pay a salary higher than the one which clears the labor market. An optimal efficiency wage is achieved when the marginal costs of an increase in wage equals the marginal benefit of the improved productivity. In this paper, we show (see (11)) that, at equilibrium, the earned income, i.e. salary plus bonus, of the worker is larger than the salary she/he gets, at equilibrium, when there is no incentive. That is due to an increase of the TFP. In some sense, the bonus corresponds to the idea of optimality.

7.

We suppose the capital depreciation rate equals 1.

8.

The function ɛ is as in the previous sections.

References

Amir, R. (1996). Sensitivity analysis of multisector optimal economic dynamics. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 25(1), 123141.

Bloom, N., Eifert, B., Mahajan, A., McKenzie, D., & Roberts, J. (2013). Does management matter? Evidence from Inida, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 151.

Hulten, C. R. (2009). Dynamic Programming in Economics, Springer Science & Business Media.

Le Van, C., & Dana, R. A. (2003), Dynamic Programming in Economics, Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Le Van, C., & Pham, N. S. (2021), “Why does productivity matter?”, Working Paper (halshs-03139392).

Leibenstein, H. (1957). The theory of underemployment in backward economies. The Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 91103.

Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 342.

Marshall, A. (1890), Principles of Economics (8th ed.). Macmillan, London.

Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 10021037.

Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Unemployment as a worker discipline device. The American Economic Review, 74(3), 433444.

Solow, R. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312320.

Solow, R. (1979). Another possible source of wage stickiness. Journal of Macroeconomics, 1(1), 7982.

Taylor, J., & Taylor, R. (2011). Working hard for more money or working hard to make a difference? efficiency wages, public service motivation and effort. Review of Public Personnel Administration, 31(1), 6786.

Zhu, X. (2012). Understanding China’s growth: Past, present, and future. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 103124.

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for very helpful comments and suggestions from the editor, and two anonymous reviewers are gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are the authors’ own.

Corresponding author

Nguyen To-The can be contacted at: tothenguyen@gmail.com

Related articles