Corruption and corporate investment efficiency around the world

Xuan Minh Nguyen (Foreign Trade University, Ho Chi Minh City Campus, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam)
Quoc Trung Tran (Foreign Trade University, Ho Chi Minh City Campus, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam)

European Journal of Management and Business Economics

ISSN: 2444-8494

Article publication date: 13 April 2022

Issue publication date: 21 September 2022

1648

Abstract

Purpose

The paper investigates the effect of corruption on corporate investment efficiency around the world.

Design/methodology/approach

The sample includes 218,350 observations from 30,074 firms across 42 countries. The authors measure corruption based on the Corruption Perception Index (CPI) from Transparency International, Corruption Control Index (CCI) from the World Bank and Corruption Index from the International Country Risk Guide.

Findings

The authors find that corruption is negatively related to investment efficiency. The robustness checks with different measures of corporate investment and alternative regression approaches show consistent findings. Moreover, the authors also find that the effect of corruption is stronger (weaker) in strong (weak) shareholder protection countries.

Originality/value

The paper has two important contributions to the literature. First, it shows that corruption environment is also a determinant of corporate investment efficiency. Second, legal protection of shareholders can mitigate the negative effect of corruption on corporate investment efficiency.

研究目的

本研究擬探討世界各地貪污腐敗對企業投資效率的影響。

研究設計/方法/理念

研究樣本涵蓋42個國家,30,074間公司,218,350個觀察。測量貪污腐敗的方法乃基於國際透明組織的腐敗感知指數、世界銀行的腐敗控制指數和國際國家風險指南的貪污指數。

研究結果

研究結果顯示、貪污與投資效率成負相關。以企業投資的各種測量方法、以及用其他的回歸分析方法來進行的強度檢驗,均顯示一致的結果。而且,我們亦發現,在對股東的保障較大的國家,貪污所帶來的影響也會較大;同樣地、對股東的保障較小的國家,貪污的影響也相應會較輕微。

研究的原創性/價值

本研究對文獻有兩個重要的貢獻。首先,研究證明了貪污腐敗的環境亦是企業投資效率的決定因素;其次,研究亦證明給股東的法律保護會減低貪污對企業投資效率所帶來的負面影響。

Keywords

Citation

Nguyen, X.M. and Tran, Q.T. (2022), "Corruption and corporate investment efficiency around the world", European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 31 No. 4, pp. 425-438. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJMBE-11-2020-0321

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2022, Xuan Minh Nguyen and Quoc Trung Tran

License

Published in European Journal of Management and Business Economics. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and noncommercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Modigliani and Miller (1958) posit that investment opportunities are the only determinant of corporate investment. Nevertheless, several market frictions are present in the real world; thus, corporate investment fails to archive its optimal status. Prior research shows that corporate investment efficiency is not only determined by firm-specific factors (Boubakri et al., 2013; Chen et al., 2006, 2017; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Jiang et al., 2011; Myers, 1977; Myers and Majluf, 1984b) but also by country-specific factors, such as shareholder protection (Xiao, 2013) and national culture (Zhang et al., 2016). Recently, the effect of corruption on corporate financial decisions has attracted much attention from academics (Baxamusa and Jalal, 2014; Thakur and Kannadhasan, 2019; Tran, 2019, 2020a; Wang and You, 2012). This paper investigates how corruption influences corporate investment efficiency.

Cai et al. (2004), Svensson (2003), Wang and You (2012), Wei and Kaufmann (1999) and Xu et al. (2017) show that firms pay bribes to government officials as “grease money” and/or “protection money”. Thakur and Kannadhasan (2019) and Tran (2020a) also find that firms in high corruption countries tend to save more cash for their bribery payment. These prior studies imply that managers in a highly corrupt environment are more flexible to use firm resources. Therefore, managers may exploit this flexibility to overinvest in unprofitable projects and reduce investment in profitable projects (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). This behavior leads to lower investment efficiency.

Following Baker et al. (2003) and Chen et al. (2017), we propose a model to examine how corruption influences the investment-investment sensitivity. Using a research sample of 218,350 firm years from 30,074 firms across 42 countries, we find that all corruption measures are negatively related to investment efficiency. Our robustness tests with various measures of corporate investment and alternative regression approaches report consistent findings. Moreover, prior research shows that legal protection of shareholders reduces agency costs and improves management quality. Therefore, we argue that the negative effect of corruption on investment efficiency is weaker in countries of strong shareholder rights. We divide the full sample into two sub-samples of strong and weak shareholder protection based on anti-self-dealing index, investor protection index and legal origin. We find that all corruption indices become more effective in corporate investment efficiency in weak shareholder protection countries.

This paper makes two contributions to the literature. First, prior studies document that corruption affects corporate financial decisions, such as cash holdings (Thakur and Kannadhasan, 2019; Tran, 2020a), dividend policy (Tahir et al., 2020; Tran, 2019), capital structure (Singh and Kannadhasan, 2020), corporate risk-taking (Chen et al., 2015b; Tran, 2020b), firm growth (Nguyen and Van Dijk, 2012) and investment growth (Asiedu and Freeman, 2009). However, they have not fully addressed how corruption determines corporate investment efficiency. This paper shows that managers take advantage of corrupt environments to increase overinvestment. Moreover, it provides additional evidence to support the negative relationship between corruption and national economic efficiency (Brunetti et al., 1998; Doh and Teegen, 2003; Gründler and Potrafke, 2019; Zakharov, 2018). Second, while prior studies investigate the effect of shareholder protection on dividend policy (La Porta et al., 2000b; Tran et al., 2017) and cash holdings (Dittmar et al., 2003; Iskandar-Datta and Jia, 2014), we examine the role of shareholder protection in mitigating the negative effect of corruption on corporate investment efficiency.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews prior studies and develops main theoretical hypotheses. Section 3 and Section 4 describe the empirical strategy and the utilized data. Section 5 presents regression results and robustness checks. Section 6 concludes.

2. Corruption and investment

2.1 Literature review

Corruption is defined as behavior driven by personal interest to exploit public power and position (Jain, 2001). Main causes of corruption include market structure (Ades and Di Tella, 1999); legal, political and socioeconomic environment (Paldam, 2002; Treisman, 2000); institutional quality (Acemoglu et al., 2001) and legal effectiveness (Herzfeld and Weiss, 2003). From a macroeconomic perspective, prior research shows that corruption tends to deteriorate economic efficiency. In a pioneer study, Mauro (1995) documents that corruption has a negative impact on investment, which in turn reduces national economic growth. Following studies also find that a high corruption environment is detrimental for investment (Brunetti et al., 1998; Doh and Teegen, 2003; Zakharov, 2018). Lambsdorff and Cornelius (2000) document that corruption negatively affects both foreign direct investment and economic growth across 26 African countries.

Although many prior macroeconomic studies consistently show the negative relationship between corruption and economic performance, the effect of corruption on economic efficiency at firm level is still debatable. Svensson (2003) and Wang and You (2012) document a positive relationship between bribery payment and firm growth. However, Nguyen and Van Dijk (2012) find that corruption is negatively related to growth of private firms. Measuring corruption by entertainment and travel costs, Cai et al. (2004) find that some components of these costs are positively associated with firm profitability despite their overall negative effect on firm productivity. Using the World Bank database of enterprise surveys, Sharma and Mitra (2015) show that the relationship between bribery and firm performance is rather mixed although they find positive effects of bribery on product innovation and export performance.

Corporate investment is important in corporate finance as it determines firm value. According to Modigliani and Miller (1958), corporate investment decisions are driven only by investment opportunities. Nevertheless, market frictions, such as information asymmetry and agency problem, make corporate investment deviate from its optimal status (Chen et al., 2017). According to Jensen and Meckling (1976), due to the separation of corporate ownership and control, managers have high incentives to serve their own benefits by overinvesting corporate cash in negative net present value (NPV) projects. Harford (1999), Jiang et al. (2011) and Richardson (2006) show supporting evidence of this behavior. Chen et al. (2017) find that foreign investors play an important role in monitoring managers and thus help firms increase their investment efficiency. At the country level, Xiao (2013) analyzes how shareholder protection affects research and development (R&D) expenditure and finds that shareholder protection reduces both underinvestment and overinvestment. Furthermore, Asiedu and Freeman (2009) use the database of the World Business Environment Survey to examine how internal, external and hybrid measures of corruption influence corporate investment growth. They find that these corruption measures are negatively associated with investment growth in transition markets. This paper investigates the effect of corruption on corporate investment efficiency and its transmitting mechanism. Unlike Asiedu and Freeman (2009), we construct our sample from Compustat database.

2.2 Hypotheses

In this paper, we argue that in corrupt environments, firms have to pay bribes in order to receive better public services (e.g. lower red tape and better access to scarce resources) and/or reduce state predation (e.g. property right protection and tax reduction) (Cai et al., 2004; Svensson, 2003; Wang and You, 2012; Wei and Kaufmann, 1999; Xu et al., 2017). Since bribes are made unofficially, managers need more flexibility in using corporate cash. Thakur and Kannadhasan (2019) and Tran (2020a) also find that firms in countries of higher corruption tend to have more cash holdings and save more cash from their cash flows. Therefore, corporate managers may take advantage of this opportunity to expropriate shareholders. Managers in high corruption countries are more likely to reduce investment in profitable projects and use more corporate cash to overinvest in negative NPV projects. Based on these arguments, we hypothesize that corruption negatively affects corporate investment efficiency.

H1.

Corruption is negatively related to corporate investment efficiency.

In addition, several prior studies document that shareholder protection is important to mitigate the agency problem in corporate financial decisions, namely dividend policy (La Porta et al., 2000b; Tran et al., 2017) and corporate liquidity (Dittmar et al., 2003; Iskandar-Datta and Jia, 2014). Therefore, we argue that the negative effect of corruption on firm investment efficiency is stronger in countries of poor shareholder rights.

H2.

The negative relationship between corruption and investment efficiency is stronger in countries of weak shareholder protection.

3. Data source

We construct our research data from Compustat database. Following Bates et al. (2009), we consider R&D expenditure as zero if it is unavailable. For subsequent analyses, we eliminate firms classified into utilities industry (SIC codes from 6,000 to 6,999) and financial industry (SIC codes from 4,900 to 4,999) since these industries are highly regulated and have different accounting standards (Fama and French, 2001). Then, we delete 149 firm years with negative total assets to avoid meaningless variables. The final sample consists of 218,350 firm years from 30,074 firms across 42 countries over the period 2002–2015. To avoid outliers' effects, we winsorize all financial variables at 2% [1].

Prior research shows that there are three prominent corruption measures including the Corruption Perception Index (CPI) from Transparency International, Corruption Control Index (CCI) from the World Bank and Corruption Index (ICI) from the International Country Risk Guide. However, each measure has its own weaknesses. According to Gründler and Potrafke (2019), the ICI tends to measure investment risk of corruption rather than corruption per se. The CCI is criticized for many problems arising from its calculation method [2] (Langbein and Knack, 2010; Qu et al., 2019). The CPI has been used as the main measure of corruption in many macroeconomic studies (Aidt, 2003, 2009; Gründler and Potrafke, 2019) and several studies at firm level (Asiedu and Freeman, 2009; Chen et al., 2015b; Tahir et al., 2020; Thakur and Kannadhasan, 2019; Tran, 2019, 2020a, b). However, its weakness is the incomparability in its calculation methodology. From 2012, Transparency International employs raw scores instead of country rankings to calculate the CPI. Therefore, we use the three corruption measures in our study in order to ensure that our findings are robust.

Before 2012, the CPI ranges from 0 to 10 but from 2012, its scale changes, and the value of CPI varies from 0 to 100. Lower values of CPI indicate higher corruption. In addition, the CCI originally ranges from −2.5 to 2.5, and its lower values also denote higher corruption. Therefore, we reverse and rescale both CPI ad CCI values so that new scales range from 0 to 1 and their higher values imply higher corruption (Please see formulas to obtain these new scales in Appendix). Besides, we fail to rescale the ICI since its scale is from 0 to 1 and its higher values indicate higher levels of corruption.

4. Empirical strategy

Following Baker et al. (2003) and Chen et al. (2017), we employ the investment-investment opportunities as a proxy for firm investment efficiency and use an interaction between corruption index and investment opportunities to investigate how corruption affects investment efficiency.

(1)INVi,j,t=α+β1TOBi,j,t1+β2CIj,t+β3TOBi,j,t1CIj,t+φiF_coni,j,t1+ηjC_conj,t+πIndustry dummies+ΩYear dummies+ωCountry dummies+εi,j,t
where Xi,j,t represents variable X of firm i in country j in year t. INV is corporate investment. TOB is Tobin's Q. CI is corruption index. F_con is a vector of firm-specific control variables including profitability (PRO), cash holdings (CAS), operating cash flow (OCF), financial leverage (LEV), asset tangibility (TAN), firm size (SIZ), net working capital (NWC) and dividend payout (DPR). Firms with high profitability, more cash holdings and cash flow tend to have higher investment expenditure since they have more resources (Chen et al., 2017). According to pecking order theory (Myers and Majluf, 1984a), firms with high leverage, low tangibility and small size face high costs of external funds; therefore, their investment is low. Increases in net working capital and dividends lead to decreases in cash holdings. Consequently, firms with high net working capital and dividend payment have low investment expenditure. C_con is a vector of country-specific control variables, namely shareholder protection (AD) (Xiao, 2013), creditor protection (CR) (González, 2016), individualistic culture (ID) [3], private credit (Pcre), market capitalization (Mcap), GDP per capita (Gcap), inflation rate (Infla) and Rule of law (Rlaw). Definitions of all variables are presented in Table 1. Since shareholder protection, creditor protection and individualistic culture are nontime-varying variables, we use pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) as the primary regression. However, we also present results of other regression methods as robustness checks.

Besides, we add dummy variables to control the effects of industry, year and country in all regression models. The incomparability problem of CPI is also controlled to some extent by year dummies [4].

5. Empirical results

5.1 Descriptive statistics

Table 2 describes our research data. Firm-specific data in Panel A shows that investment expenditure constitutes from 0% to 53% of total assets, and its average value is 9%. Tobin's Q is 1.82 on average. It varies from 0.49 to 10.67. In addition, Panel B reports that the annual number of firms increases dramatically over the research period. There are 11,127 firms in 2002 and 18,333 firms in 2015. Furthermore, the industry distribution in Panel C shows that manufacturing is the largest industry with 119,275 firm years, followed by service industry with 40,701 firm years and mineral industries with 16,155 firm years. The number of observations from other industries varies from 7,100 to 14,000. Moreover, Panel D presents country-level data. The USA contribute the largest amount of firm years to the research sample with 49,263. Japan and China have 31,119 and 20,194 observations, respectively. These three countries constitute about 46% observations of the full sample. This sample composition problem may lead to biased results, but it is present regardless of data source. Therefore, we need to use a reduced sample without these countries in order to check the robustness of our research findings.

5.2 Regression results

Table 3 presents pooled OLS regression results to investigate how corruption affects corporate investment efficiency. In line with Modigliani and Miller (1958), we find that Tobin's Q is positively related to firm investment at 1% of significance. This indicates that firms with more investment opportunities tend to increase their investment expenditure. Remarkably, we document that the interactions between all measures of corruption and Tobin's Q are negatively associated with investment expenditure. These findings imply that corruption reduces corporate investment efficiency across countries due to agency problem. Firms in highly corrupt countries tend to pay bribes as “grease money” (e.g. payment for lower red tape and better access to scarce resources) and/or “protection money” (e.g. payment for property right protection and tax reduction) (Cai et al., 2004; Svensson, 2003; Wang and You, 2012; Wei and Kaufmann, 1999; Xu et al., 2017). Therefore, their managers are more flexible in corporate liquidity decisions (Thakur and Kannadhasan, 2019; Tran, 2020a). They take this opportunity to expropriate shareholders by reducing investment in profitable projects and diverting more investment into negative NPV projects. This expropriation leads to lower investment efficiency.

Besides, we find that firms with higher cash holdings and cash flow tend to have higher investment. In line with Myers and Majluf (1984a), firms with higher leverage and lower tangibility incur higher costs of external financing; therefore, they have lower investment. Net working capital is a substitute of cash holdings and dividends are cash distribution. Consequently, they negatively affect firm investment. Moreover, the negative relationship between antiself-dealing index and investment expenditure indicates that shareholder protection may reduce overinvestment (Xiao, 2013). Consistent with Shao et al. (2013b), individualism positively influences firm investment.

5.3 Robustness checks

In order to ensure that our research findings are stable, we conduct the following robustness checks. First, we replicate all regression models with a reduced sample without USA, Japan and China. These countries contribute approximately 46% of firm years in the research sample. Consequently, our regression results may be driven by them. Panel A of Table 4 shows that all measures of corruption are still negatively related to corporate investment efficiency.

Since investment is measured by total capital expenditure and R&D expenditure in our baseline model, our results may be driven by capital expenditure or R&D expenditure only. Therefore, we replicate all regression models with alternative investment measures, including capital expenditure and R&D expenditure. Our robustness checks in Panel B of Table 4 indicate that our key findings remain unchanged.

Third, we use other regression approaches including weighted least squares regression and Fama and MacBeth (1973) regression. According to Chen et al. (2015a), the former is able to mitigate the problem of heteroscedasticity since corporate investment's variance is likely to vary strongly among a group of countries. The weight is defined as the inverse value of investment expenditure's within-country variance. Moreover, although the main tests have many country-level controls, we are still concerned that the research results may be determined by observations from certain years; therefore, we run Fama and MacBeth (1973) regression to control the effects of particular periods. Regression results for alternative approaches in Panel C of Table 4 show that all measures of corruption still negatively affect corporate investment efficiency.

6. The role of shareholder protection

We divide the full sample into two sub-samples of weak and strong shareholder rights in order to investigate how shareholder protection affects the relationship between corruption and investment efficiency. This classification is based on antiself-dealing index of Djankov et al. (2008), investor protection index La Porta et al. (2006) and legal origin. Antiself-dealing index and investor protection index range from 0 to 1. A country is defined as a strong (weak) shareholder protection if its antiself-dealing index or investor protection index is higher (not higher) than 0.5. Moreover, prior research also finds that most Common law (Civil law) countries are strong (weaker) in shareholder rights (Shao et al., 2013a); therefore, we also consider Common law (Civil law) countries as strong (weak) shareholder protection. Comparing regression results for the two groups, we find that the interaction between Tobin's Q and corruption index is more effective in strong shareholder protection countries. These findings are consistent with the role shareholder protection in mitigating agency problem (La Porta et al., 2000a; Tran, 2020c). Corporate managers in countries of high corruption may take advantage of the flexibility in corporate liquidity policy to expropriate shareholders. However, legal protection of shareholders is effective in controlling this behavior (see Table 5).

7. Conclusion

Corruption is one of the most challenging issues around the world. Many prior studies show that it significantly affects corporate financial decisions; however, there has been no research on the relationship between corruption and investment efficiency. With a sample of 218,350 observations from 30,074 firms across 42 countries, we find that corruption measures are negatively associated with investment efficiency. Our robustness checks with different measures of corporate investment and alternative regression approaches show consistent findings. These understandings indicate that corruption environment also reduces economic efficiency at firm level. Consequently, international investors should choose countries of low corruption when they seek for an investment destination. In addition, this empirical evidence implies that policymakers should enhance their anti-corruption activities in order to improve economic efficiency. Moreover, we also find that the effect of corruption is stronger (weaker) in strong (weak) shareholder protection countries. As a result, policymakers can reduce the effect of corruption environment on corporate investment efficiency by improving shareholder rights. This paper only investigates the country-level corruption on corporate investment efficiency; therefore, further research may focus on the effect of local corruption or bribery payment on corporate investment efficiency.

Research variables

VariablesVariable namesDefinitions
INVtCorporate investmentTotal capital expenditure and R&D expenditure in year t divided by total assets in year t−1
TOBt−1Tobin's QTotal market value of common equity and book value of debt divided by total assets in year t−1
CItCorruption indexCorruption perception index from transparency international, control of corruption index from world bank and corruption index from international country risk guide in year t
PROt−1ProfitabilityNet income to total assets in year t−1
CASt−1Cash holdingsCash and short-term investment to total assets in year t−1
OCFt−1Cash flowOperating cash flow to total assets in year t−1
LEVt−1Financial leverageTotal debt to total assets in year t−1
TANt−1Asset tangibilityProperty, plant and equipment to total assets in year t−1
SIZt−1Firm sizeNatural logarithm of total assets in USD in year t−1
NWCt−1Net working capitalCurrent assets minus current liabilities, cash and short-term investment divided by total assets in year t−1
DPRt−1Dividend payout ratioCash dividends to total assets in year t−1
ADShareholder protectionAnti-self-dealing index from Djankov et al. (2008)
CRCreditor protectionRevised creditor right index from Djankov et al. (2007)
IDIndividualistic cultureIndividualism index from Hofstede (2001)
PcretPrivate creditDomestic private credit to GDP provided by world bank in year t
McaptStock market capitalizationStock market capitalization to GDP provided world bank in year t
GcaptGDP per capitaNatural logarithm of annual GDP per capita provided by world bank in year t
InflatInflation rateAnnual inflation rate provided by world bank in year t
RlawRule of lawRule of law index is from international country risk guide. It ranges from 0 to 10 and its higher scores imply more tradition of law and order

Research data description

Panel A. Firm-level data
VariablesMeanMedianSD25%75%MinMax
INVt0.090.050.110.020.110.000.53
TOBt−11.821.221.820.911.910.4910.67
PROt−1−0.030.030.23−0.020.06−1.160.22
CASt−10.170.110.180.040.240.000.76
OCFt−10.190.220.370.060.40−1.340.82
LEVt−10.510.490.270.310.660.061.41
TANt−10.290.250.220.100.430.010.84
SIZt−112.1112.092.0710.7513.447.4616.76
NWCt−10.010.020.20−0.080.13−0.650.42
DPRt−10.010.000.020.000.020.000.10
Panel B. Annual number of firms
YearNYearNYearNYearN
200211,127200614,286201016,796201418,551
200312,675200715,198201116,898201518,333
200413,180200815,671201217,835
200513,357200916,004201318,439
Panel C. Industry distribution
Industry2-digit SICNIndustry2-digit SICN
Mineral industries10–1416,155Wholesale trade50–5110,346
Construction industries15–177,151Retail trade52–5910,788
Manufacturing20–39119,275Service industries≥7040,701
Transportation and communications40–4813,934
Panel D. Country-level data
CountryNo. obsNo. firmsINVTOBIDADCR
Australia11,3371,7540.132.08900.763
Austria569690.091.34550.213
Belgium8321050.101.50750.542
Brazil1,9752690.072.89380.271
Canada9,4401,6570.142.02800.641
Switzerland1,7932000.081.78680.271
Chile8201210.064.08230.632
China20,1942,4730.082.26200.762
Colombia155250.051.20130.570
Germany5,1916550.081.52670.283
Denmark7611190.101.98740.463
Spain8621170.051.54510.372
Finland1,0951350.091.60630.461
France5,3956890.071.49710.380
United Kingdom8,9441,3970.091.83890.954
Greece1,9492290.041.10350.221
Hong Kong1,2721390.061.48250.964
Hungary166240.091.37800.181
Indonesia2,7353730.072.51140.652
India15,7552,6560.081.43480.582
Ireland391600.081.62700.791
Israel2,0993550.092.36540.733
Italy1,5352320.051.32760.422
Jamaica26110.051.38390.352
Japan31,1193,0530.051.12460.501
South Korea9,1861,4470.071.12180.473
Mexico786980.071.32300.170
Malaysia7,5088400.051.14260.953
Netherlands1,3951760.071.58800.203
Norway1,5122440.102.35690.422
New Zealand5931200.092.09790.954
Pakistan1,6952570.071.33140.411
Peru522740.071.44160.450
Philippines1,0081470.061.98320.221
Poland2,9294900.071.51600.291
Portugal434520.041.18270.441
Singapore5,0486290.061.27201.003
Sweden2,6694760.071.93710.331
Thailand4,3414920.071.44200.812
Turkey1,5122600.072.13370.432
USA49,2637,1520.122.47910.651
South Africa1,5392030.081.52650.813

Note(s): INVt is corporate investment in year t. TOBt−1 is Tobin's Q in year t−1. CIt is corruption index in year t. PROt−1 is profitability in year t−1. CASt−1 is cash holdings in year t−1. OCFt−1 is operating cash flow in year t−1. LEVt−1 is financial leverage in year t−1. TANt−1 is asset tangibility in year t−1. SIZt−1 is firm size in year t−1. NWCt−1 is net working capital in year t−1. DPR is dividend payout ratio in year t−1

Corruption and corporate investment efficiency

VariablesCI is based on the Corruption Perception IndexCI is based on the Corruption Control IndexCI is based on the International Country Risk Guide
Intercept−0.0234 (−1.20)−0.0523*** (−3.01)0.0203 (1.08)
TOBi,t−10.0217*** (29.95)0.0223*** (29.27)0.0129*** (22.51)
CIt0.0694*** (8.61)0.1311*** (6.06)0.0065*** (3.37)
TOB i,t−1*CIt−0.0257*** (−17.59)−0.0300*** (−17.29)−0.0009* (−1.91)
PROi,t−1−0.1218*** (−18.27)−0.1224*** (−18.34)−0.1300*** (−19.28)
CASi,t−10.0719*** (10.39)0.0716*** (10.35)0.0759*** (10.89)
OCFi,t−10.0727*** (12.03)0.0727*** (12.01)0.0733*** (11.99)
LEVi,t−1−0.0167*** (−7.49)−0.0166*** (−7.44)−0.0147*** (−6.56)
TANi,t−10.1070*** (46.97)0.1070*** (46.97)0.1067*** (46.40)
SIZi,t−10.0002 (0.66)0.0002 (0.68)0.0002 (0.79)
NWCi,t−1−0.0721*** (−10.76)−0.0725*** (−10.81)−0.0737*** (−10.91)
DPRi,t−1−0.1848*** (−10.55)−0.1864*** (−10.63)−0.1847*** (−10.35)
AD−0.0254* (−1.87)−0.0158 (−1.33)−0.0164 (−1.21)
CR−0.0067** (−2.48)−0.0110*** (−3.67)−0.0059** (−2.22)
ID0.0006*** (8.15)0.0008*** (8.04)0.0005*** (8.57)
Pcret0.0001*** (3.71)0.0001*** (4.08)0.0001*** (4.56)
Mcapt0.0001*** (6.98)0.0001*** (6.78)0.0000*** (6.24)
Gcapt−0.0035** (−2.44)−0.0044*** (−3.03)−0.0062*** (−4.22)
Inflat−0.0010*** (−5.64)−0.0009*** (−5.28)−0.0011*** (−5.97)
Rlaw0.0102*** (10.15)0.0107*** (10.59)0.0073*** (5.87)
Industry dummiesYesYesYes
Year dummiesYesYesYes
Country dummiesYesYesYes
Clustered by firmYesYesYes
R-squared0.26830.26810.2623
Number of observations218,045218,045218,045

Note(s): The dependent variable is corporate investment in year t (INVt). TOB is Tobin's Q. CI is corruption index. PRO is profitability. CAS is cash holdings. OCF is operating cash flow. LEV is financial leverage. TAN is asset tangibility. SIZ is firm size. NWC is net working capital. DPR is dividend payout ratio. AD is shareholder protection index. CR is creditor protection. ID is Hofstede's individualism dimension. Pcre is private credit to GDP. Mcap is market capitalization to GDP. Gcap is annual GDP per capita. Inlfat is annual inflation rate in year t. Rlawt is rule of law in year t. t-statistics are in parentheses. * is 10% of significance. ** is 5% of significance. *** is 1% of significance

Robustness checks

VariablesCI is based on the Corruption Perception IndexCI is based on the Corruption Control IndexCI is based on the International Country Risk Guide
Panel A. Reduced sample without USA, Japan and China
TOBi,t−10.0223*** (22.81)0.0229*** (23.31)0.0118*** (16.64)
CIt0.0581*** (5.77)−0.0085 (−0.58)0.0065*** (2.76)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0272*** (−14.62)−0.0329*** (−15.52)−0.0005* (−1.77)
Panel B. Alternative measures of firm investment
Capital expenditure
TOBi,t−10.0043*** (16.89)0.0043*** (16.37)0.0035*** (16.87)
CIt0.0102** (2.21)0.0161 (1.45)0.0032*** (3.39)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0032*** (−5.00)−0.0037*** (−5.03)−0.0008** (−2.27)
R&D expenditure
TOBi,t−10.0055*** (12.10)0.0058*** (12.22)0.0030*** (9.11)
CIt0.0338*** (8.94)0.0423*** (3.56)0.0042*** (4.32)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0078*** (−9.40)−0.0094*** (−9.61)−0.0006* (−1.74)
Panel C. Alternative regression approaches
Weighted least squares regression
TOBi,t−10.0198*** (76.68)0.0199*** (75.98)0.0115*** (39.93)
CIt0.0614*** (10.89)0.0976*** (8.04)0.0069*** (4.39)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0227*** (−39.92)−0.0258*** (−39.55)−0.0017*** (−3.14)
Fama–Macbeth regression
TOBi,t−10.0218*** (29.62)0.0225*** (25.16)0.0134*** (5.96)
CIt0.0193* (1.89)0.0192* (1.91)0.0014 (0.22)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0262*** (−14.20)−0.0307*** (−14.01)−0.0024* (−1.73)

Note(s): The dependent variable is corporate investment in year t (INVt). TOB is Tobin's Q. CI is corruption index. t-statistics are in parentheses. * is 10% of significance. ** is 5% of significance. *** is 1% of significance

The relationship between corruption and corporate investment efficiency by shareholder protection

VariablesWeak shareholder protectionStrong shareholder protection
AD ≤ 0.5IP ≤ 0.5AD > 0.5IP > 0.5
Panel A. CI is based on the Corruption Perception Index
TOBi,t−10.0197*** (12.17)0.0218*** (26.27)0.0217*** (26.20)0.0205*** (12.82)
CIt0.0874*** (7.25)0.0874*** (7.04)0.0680*** (4.65)0.0303** (2.41)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0238*** (−8.10)−0.0251*** (−14.44)−0.0251*** (−14.25)−0.0260*** (−8.94)
Panel B. CI is based on the Corruption Control Index
TOBi,t−10.0196*** (12.70)0.0199*** (13.19)0.0227*** (25.43)0.0228*** (25.48)
CIt0.1244*** (3.61)0.1370** (2.27)0.0290 (0.00)0.0360 (1.39)
TOBi,t−1*CIt−0.0271*** (−8.66)−0.0284*** (−9.27)−0.0307*** (−14.21)−0.0308*** (−14.40)
Panel C. CI is based on the International Country Risk Guide
TOBi,t−10.0102*** (9.42)0.0135*** (20.36)0.0138*** (20.56)0.0117*** (10.37)
CIt−0.0007 (−0.23)0.0077*** (3.07)0.0079*** (3.11)0.0027 (0.86)
TOBi,t−1*CIt0.0003 (0.16)−0.0014 (−1.32)−0.0018* (−1.68)−0.0021 (−1.02)

Note(s): The dependent variable is corporate investment in year t (INVt). TOB is Tobin's Q. CI is corruption index. t-statistics are in parentheses. * is 10% of significance. ** is 5% of significance. *** is 1% of significance

Notes

1.

We also winsorize financial variables at 3 and 5% and our research findings remain stable.

2.

ICI captures the spheres of illegal activity as follows: “actual or potential corruption in the form of excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, ‘favor-for-favors’, secret party funding and suspiciously close ties between politics and business”.

3.

Shao et al. (2013b) posit that individualism dimension is the best proxy for national culture since it prevails in most cultural frameworks and more relevant to risk taking. We also find consistent findings, adding other dimensions including masculinity and uncertainty avoidance.

4.

We also conduct a robustness check by adding a period dummy to Equation (1) in order to control the incomparability problem of CPI. The dummy is assigned 1 for observations before 2012 and 0 otherwise. We find that our key findings remain stable.

Appendix Rescaling corruption indices

CI based on Transparency International's Corruption Perception Index (CPI) = {1 CPI10 if year<20121CPI100 if year 2012

CI based on the World Bank's Corruption Control Index (CCI) = 5 – CCI*2

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J.A. (2001), “The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation”, American Economic Review, Vol. 91 No. 5, pp. 1369-1401.

Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1999), “Rents, competition, and corruption”, American Economic Review, Vol. 89 No. 4, pp. 982-993.

Aidt, T.S. (2003), “Economic analysis of corruption: a survey”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 113 No. 491, pp. F632-F652.

Aidt, T.S. (2009), “Corruption, institutions, and economic development”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 25 No. 2, pp. 271-291.

Asiedu, E. and Freeman, J. (2009), “The effect of corruption on investment growth: evidence from firms in Latin America, Sub-Saharan Africa, and transition countries”, Review of Development Economics, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 200-214.

Baker, M., Stein, J.C. and Wurgler, J. (2003), “When does the market matter? Stock prices and the investment of equity-dependent firms”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 No. 3, pp. 969-1005.

Bates, T.W., Kahle, K.M. and Stulz, R.M. (2009), “Why do US firms hold so much more cash than they used to?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 64 No. 5, pp. 1985-2021.

Baxamusa, M. and Jalal, A. (2014), “The effects of corruption on capital structure: when does it matter?”, The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 315-335.

Boubakri, N., Cosset, J.-C. and Saffar, W. (2013), “The role of state and foreign owners in corporate risk-taking: evidence from privatization”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 108 No. 3, pp. 641-658.

Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G. and Weder, B. (1998), “Credibility of rules and economic growth: evidence from a worldwide survey of the private sector”, The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 353-384.

Cai, H., Fang, H. and Xu, L.C. (2004), “Eat, drink, firms and government: an investigation of corruption from entertainment expenditures of chinese firms”, The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 54 No. 1, pp. 55-78.

Chen, Q., Goldstein, I. and Jiang, W. (2006), “Price informativeness and investment sensitivity to stock price”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 20 No. 3, pp. 619-650.

Chen, Y., Dou, P.Y., Rhee, S.G., Truong, C. and Veeraraghavan, M. (2015a), “National culture and corporate cash holdings around the world”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 50, pp. 1-18.

Chen, M., Jeon, B.N., Wang, R. and Wu, J. (2015b), “Corruption and bank risk-taking: evidence from emerging economies”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 24, pp. 122-148.

Chen, R., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O. and Wang, H. (2017), “Do state and foreign ownership affect investment efficiency? Evidence from privatizations”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 42, pp. 408-421.

Dittmar, A., Mahrt-Smith, J. and Servaes, H. (2003), “International corporate governance and corporate cash holdings”, Journal of Financial Quantitative analysisJournal of Financial, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 111-133.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C. and Shleifer, A. (2007), “Private credit in 129 countries”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 84 No. 2, pp. 299-329.

Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2008), “The law and economics of self-dealing”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 88 No. 3, pp. 430-465.

Doh, J.P. and Teegen, H.J. (2003), “Private telecommunications investment in emerging economies: comparing the Latin American and Asian experience”, Management Research: Journal of the Iberoamerican Academy of Management, Vol. 1 No. 1, pp. 9-26.

Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (2001), “Disappearing dividends: changing firm characteristics or lower propensity to pay?”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 60 No. 1, pp. 3-43.

Fama, E.F. and MacBeth, J.D. (1973), “Risk, return, and equilibrium: empirical tests”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81 No. 3, pp. 607-636.

González, F. (2016), “Creditor rights, bank competition, and corporate investment during the global financial crisis”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 37, pp. 249-270.

Gründler, K. and Potrafke, N. (2019), “Corruption and economic growth: new empirical evidence”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 60, p. 101810.

Harford, J. (1999), “Corporate cash reserves and acquisitions”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 54 No. 6, pp. 1969-1997.

Herzfeld, T. and Weiss, C. (2003), “Corruption and legal (in)effectiveness: an empirical investigation”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 621-632.

Hofstede, G. (2001), Culture's Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions and Organizations across Nations, Sage Publications.

Iskandar-Datta, M.E. and Jia, Y. (2014), “Investor protection and corporate cash holdings around the world: new evidence”, Review of Quantitative Finance, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 245-273.

Jain, A.K. (2001), “Corruption: a review”, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp. 71-121.

Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976), “Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 No. 4, pp. 305-360.

Jiang, L., Kim, J.-B. and Pang, L. (2011), “Control-ownership wedge and investment sensitivity to stock price”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 35 No. 11, pp. 2856-2867.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (2000a), “Investor protection and corporate governance”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 58 Nos 1-2, pp. 3-27.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (2000b), “Agency problems and dividend policies around the world”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 55 No. 1, pp. 1-33.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2006), “What works in securities laws?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 61 No. 1, pp. 1-32.

Lambsdorff, J.G. and Cornelius, P. (2000), “Corruption, foreign investment and growth”, The Africa Competitiveness Report, Vol. 2001, pp. 70-78.

Langbein, L. and Knack, S. (2010), “The Worldwide governance indicators: six, one, or none?”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 46 No. 2, pp. 350-370.

Mauro, P. (1995), “Corruption and growth”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110 No. 3, pp. 681-712.

Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H. (1958), “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment”, The American, Vol. 1, p. 3.

Myers, S.C. (1977), “Determinants of corporate borrowing”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 147-175.

Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S. (1984a), “Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 187-221.

Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S. (1984b), “Stock issues and investment policy when firms have information that investors do not have”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 13, p. 24.

Nguyen, T.T. and Van Dijk, M.A. (2012), “Corruption, growth, and governance: private vs state-owned firms in Vietnam”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 36 No. 11, pp. 2935-2948.

Paldam, M. (2002), “The cross-country pattern of corruption: economics, culture and the seesaw dynamics”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 215-240.

Qu, G., Slagter, B., Sylwester, K. and Doiron, K. (2019), “Explaining the standard errors of corruption perception indices”, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 47 No. 4, pp. 907-920.

Richardson, S. (2006), “Over-investment of free cash flow”, Review of Accounting Studies, Vol. 11 Nos 2-3, pp. 159-189.

Shao, L., Kwok, C.C.Y. and Guedhami, O. (2013a), “Dividend policy: balancing shareholders' and creditors' interests”, Journal of Financial Research, Vol. 36 No. 1, pp. 43-66.

Shao, L., Kwok, C.C.Y. and Zhang, R. (2013b), “National culture and corporate investment”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 44 No. 7, pp. 745-763.

Sharma, C. and Mitra, A. (2015), “Corruption, governance and firm performance: evidence from Indian enterprises”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 37 No. 5, pp. 835-851.

Singh, B.P. and Kannadhasan, M. (2020), “Corruption and capital structure in emerging markets: a panel quantile regression approach”, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, Vol. 28, p. 100417.

Svensson, J. (2003), “Who must pay bribes and how much? Evidence from a cross-section of firms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118, pp. 207-230.

Tahir, M., Ibrahim, H., Zulkafli, A.H. and Mushtaq, M. (2020), “Corruption, national culture, law and dividend repatriation policy”, Journal of Multinational Financial Management, Vols 57-58, p. 100658.

Thakur, B.P.S. and Kannadhasan, M. (2019), “Corruption and cash holdings: evidence from emerging market economies”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 38, pp. 1-17.

Tran, Q.T. (2019), “Corruption, agency costs and dividend policy: international evidence”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 76, pp. 325-334.

Tran, Q.T. (2020a), “Corruption and corporate cash holdings: international evidence”, Journal of Multinational Financial Management, Vol. 54, p. 100611.

Tran, Q.T. (2020b), “Corruption and corporate risk-taking: evidence from emerging markets”, International Journal of Emerging Markets.

Tran, Q.T. (2020c), “Financial crisis, shareholder protection and cash holdings”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 52, p. 101131.

Tran, Q.T., Alphonse, P. and Nguyen, X.M. (2017), “Dividend policy: shareholder rights and creditor rights under the impact of the global financial crisis”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 64, pp. 502-512.

Treisman, D. (2000), “The causes of corruption: a cross-national study”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76 No. 3, pp. 399-457.

Wang, Y. and You, J. (2012), “Corruption and firm growth: evidence from China”, China Economic Review, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 415-433.

Wei, S.-J. and Kaufmann, D. (1999), Does Grease Money Speed up the Wheels of Commerce?, The World Bank.

Xiao, G. (2013), “Legal shareholder protection and corporate R&D investment”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 23, pp. 240-266.

Xu, G., Zhang, D. and Yano, G. (2017), “Can corruption really function as ‘protection money’ and ‘grease money’? Evidence from Chinese firms”, Economic Systems, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 622-638.

Zakharov, N. (2018), “Does corruption hinder investment? Evidence from Russian regions”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 56, pp. 39-61.

Zhang, M., Zhang, W. and Zhang, S. (2016), “National culture and firm investment efficiency: international evidence”, Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 1-21.

Corresponding author

Quoc Trung Tran can be contacted at: tranquoctrung.cs2@ftu.edu.vn; quoctrungftu@gmail.com

Related articles