Market structure, institutional quality and bank capital ratios: evidence from developing countries

Oyebola Fatima Etudaiye-Muhtar (University of Ilorin, Ilorin, Nigeria)
Zayyad Abdul-Baki (Prince Sultan University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia)

European Journal of Management and Business Economics

ISSN: 2444-8494

Article publication date: 5 August 2020

Issue publication date: 12 February 2021

2242

Abstract

Purpose

This paper investigates the role of market structure and institutional quality in determining bank capital ratios in developing economies.

Design/methodology/approach

The generalised methods of moment technique is used to control for auto-correlation and endogeneity in a sample of 79 publicly listed commercial banks. The study period is between 2000 and 2016.

Findings

Results show that market structure (proxied with bank competition) as well as institutional quality (regulatory quality) lowers bank capital in the sampled banks. This suggests that banks operating in less competitive markets with good regulatory quality do not need to engage in excessive risk-taking activities that would necessitate holding increased level of capital. Furthermore, the interaction of competition and regulatory quality reinforces the main findings, suggesting the importance of the two variables in determining bank capital ratio.

Research limitations/implications

Research has limitation in that the study investigated publicly listed commercial banks, the findings may not be applicable to non-listed banks.

Practical implications

Taking into cognisance the developing nature of the banking system in Africa, the findings from this study imply that the maintenance of an improved regulatory quality in an environment where healthy competition exists would encourage banks to hold capital ratios appropriate for their level of banking activities, that is, the banks would not engage in excessive risk-taking activities.

Originality/value

This is one of the first papers that examine the effect of market structure and institutional quality on bank capital ratios in developing countries that have bank-based financial systems.

Keywords

Citation

Etudaiye-Muhtar, O.F. and Abdul-Baki, Z. (2021), "Market structure, institutional quality and bank capital ratios: evidence from developing countries", European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 92-107. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJMBE-09-2019-0158

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2020, Oyebola Fatima Etudaiye-Muhtar and Zayyad Abdul-Baki

License

Published in European Journal of Management and Business Economics. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Bank capital plays a significant role in maintaining the stability of any financial system because it not only supports daily operations of the bank but also reassures relevant stakeholders in the industry of the continued existence of the bank. However, some banks maintain capital in excess of what regulatory bodies specify, and extant literature provides several reasons why this is so. For example, high adjustment costs may be incurred by banks which fall short of minimum capital ratios in the process of adjusting back to the minimum. To prevent these costs, banks may decide to hold capital in excess of regulatory requirements so that they are above the minimum required at any point in time (Alraheb et al., 2019). Banks may also hold excess capital to meet up with unexpected investment opportunities and to mitigate a rise in risks associated with increase in credit facilities when efficient supervision is absent (Milne, 2002; Vithessonthi, 2014). Such risky behaviour, when it goes bad, erodes bank capital. To prevent capital erosion, regulatory bodies put in place minimum capital requirements for banks that serve as disciplinary mechanisms to dissuade banks' management from taking unnecessary risks that would adversely affect banks' capital (Anginer et al., 2018). The disciplinary measure has, however, not prevented banks from engaging in excessive risks as evidenced in the sub-prime mortgage/global financial crisis of 2007–2009 where most of the troubled financial institutions had their capital ratios above the minimum required level prior to the crisis (Anginer et al., 2018). Moreover, Calomiris and Jaremski (2016) argue that weaker market discipline by depositors may provide an impetus for banks to reduce capital ratios and engage in risky lending.

Market structure viewed in terms of bank competition lowers market power, earnings and franchise value, making banks engage in excessive risk-taking in order to increase capital ratios to mitigate losses that may arise from such risks (Liu et al., 2013) [1]. Similarly, Allen et al. (2011) argue that competition encourages banks to have higher capital levels because it (competition) displays the level of commitment a bank has towards effective monitoring and attracting creditworthy customers. Extant literature also shows that customer’s lending behaviour, shareholder's rights and deposit insurance influence the level of capital a bank would have. Whereas information-sensitive customers and strong shareholder's rights encourage higher capital, the presence of deposit insurance lowers bank capital (Allen et al., 2011). The implication of these arguments is that strong institutions should exist alongside higher bank capital ratios. Furthermore, development of quality institutions is crucial to maintaining financial stability and resistance to local or international shocks as observed in the 2007/2008 global financial crisis (Alraheb et al., 2019).

The financial system in African countries is mostly bank-based, underscoring the importance of banks in the system and the role it plays in maintaining the stability of the financial system to ensure growth of the economy (Ozili, 2018). One way of maintaining stability is for banks to have adequate capital to support its business activities (Chiaramonte and Casu, 2017; Ozili, 2018). The ripple effect of the 2007–2009 global financial crisis also made most African countries to put in place regulatory measures that would enhance financial stability through increased capital ratios. For instance, in keeping up with the BASEL III requirements concerning capital, commercial banks in Kenya were required to raise their capital to $12.5 million by 2012, from $3.3 million in 2008. Similarly, Zambian commercial banks had to increase their minimum capital to $2.2 million, from $358,240. In Algeria, the minimum capital was increased to $155 million, from $39 million (Oduor et al., 2017). However, the presence of institution-related issues such as poor regulatory quality, inaccurate information disclosure and poor corporate governance policies poses a challenge to the maintenance of adequate capital by banks in developing countries (Alraheb et al., 2019; Anginer et al., 2018). This implies that banks in such countries would hold just enough capital to meet regulatory requirements which would create moral hazard especially where capital is costly (Allen et al., 2012).

This study contributes to existing literature in a number of ways. First, it is the first study that investigates the role played by competition (as a form of market structure) and regulatory quality (to capture institutional quality) in determining bank capital ratios in publicly listed commercial banks in African countries. Given the scarcity of literature from this region and other developing countries, two recent works related to our study are by Otero et al. (2017, 2019). While the former investigated competition, concentration and risk-taking, the latter study examined market structure, performance and efficiency, with both studies focusing on the Middle East and North African (MENA) region. Our study deviates from these two studies by examining the role played by market structure and institutional quality on bank capital ratio in African countries. Our results provide empirical evidence from the banking sector of developing countries where banks operate in challenging environments and there is a higher probability of destabilisation due to capital erosion than in developed countries where the issues are less severe. Second, noting that previous studies mostly focused on how bank-level and macroeconomic factors affect bank capital ratio (Flamini et al., 2009; Francis, 2013; Ozili, 2015), we carry out our investigation on African banks by focusing on market structure and institutional quality because the region had witnessed varying levels of positive development in the quality of institutions and the opening up of its economy to international integration. The financial and trade openness suggests more entry into the financial sector and may induce a more competitive and efficient sector that could drive bank performance that would enhance stability in the system (Otero et al., 2019).

In our empirical analysis, we consider the endogeneity of bank capital and use the two-step system generalised moment method (Sys-GMM) for the investigation. The results reveal that bank competition and regulatory quality lower bank capital, suggesting that in less competitive markets where the regulatory quality is high, banks do not need to engage in excessive risk-taking activities that would necessitate holding increased levels of capital. These findings are strengthened when we investigate whether competition is conditioned on the quality of existing regulation.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: In Section 2, we discuss related literature. Section 3 addresses the methodology employed in the study in terms of model, method and variables. Section 4 discusses the results. We conclude the paper in Section 5 with relevant policy implications.

2. Related literature

Theoretical literature provides insights on why banks hold capital in excess of what is required by regulatory authorities. One is the capital buffer theory where proponents of the theory argue that even in the absence of regulation, a bank would need to maintain an appropriate capital level because the market requires them to do so to remain in business. For instance, Berger (1995) and Berger et al. (1995) argue that banks have capital in excess of regulatory requirement to take advantage of unexpected profitable opportunities or to absorb unanticipated losses. Where regulation exists, banks may hold excess capital to avoid high adjustment costs and penalties that may result from being unable to meet minimum regulatory requirements (Rime, 2001). Another theory is the charter or franchise value where bank earnings are important in determining bank capital ratios. Here, bank managers build up capital from high earnings, and cost efficiency to guard against liquidation and high capital ratios indicate bank quality (Demstez et al., 1996). Keeley (1990) explains bank charter value as the present value of future profits that banks expect to earn from operations and banks would choose high capital to protect its charter. Thus, reduced earnings may lead a bank to engage in risky projects to reverse the fall. The trade-off theory is also important because anticipated rise in bankruptcy costs due to an increase in asset portfolio could imply an increase in insolvency risk. To prevent this, banks increase their capital-to-assets ratio, and ultimately the capital ratio (Berger, 1995). In terms of market structure/competition, Allen et al. (2011) presented a model where market competition encourages banks to hold excess capital for several reasons such as indicating banks' commitment to monitoring and attracting creditworthy and information-sensitive borrowers. Higher capital ratios also depict the presence of strong shareholder rights protection, while deposit insurance reduces capital ratio. Recently, Alraheb et al. (2019) showed that institutional variables significantly influence bank capital ratios in MENA countries, depending on the level of financial market development. They found that institutional qualities are important in determining bank capital ratio in countries where the stock market is less developed. This further reinforces our motivation for this study given that the financial system in the region is bank-based and research-focused on institutions is lacking from this region. In addition, Anginer et al. (2018), while investigating ways by which institutional environment affect bank capital and fragility, found that systemic risk lowers bank capital and is more obvious for banks operating in less developed markets where issues such as information asymmetry and inefficient supervision are present. The authors established that capital may be used to replace a weak institutional environment to reduce systemic risk. However, the extent to which this is applicable to African banks is not known. Related literature on bank competition is concerned with improving stability of the financial system while maintaining a healthy competition between financial institutions. For instance, Liu et al. (2013), using a competition index that indicated how much capital a bank has to cushion the effect of unforeseen losses as a proxy for fragility, show that in regional markets in the European Union, increased (decreased) competition seems to improve (worsen) stability in uncompetitive banking environments unlike what is obtainable in more competitive markets where fragility is increased. As observed by Beck and Cull (2013), the banking environment in African countries is not as competitive as the ones in more developed economies; thus, we expect results that are different from what is obtainable in developed financial systems.

Besides the preceding theoretical discussion on bank capital, literature also suggests that bank-specific factors may influence the level of capital a bank holds. An example is bank size which may exert either a positive or negative effect on capital. In terms of positive effect, large-sized banks derive certain benefits for being big. For instance, lower costs of raising additional capital due to benefits resulting from economies of scale enable large-sized banks to acquire more capital at a lower cost than smaller-sized banks (De Jonghe and Öztekin, 2015). Furthermore, large banks may consider maintaining excess capital to have good ratings that will promote operations (Jackson et al., 2002). However, due to the “too-big-to-fail” condition where regulators are unwilling to close big banks, a large-sized bank may choose to hold less capital than a small-sized bank, suggesting that size does not matter (Luc Laeven et al., 2016). Another important factor is bank liquidity because more liquid assets and better capitalised banks are considered as safer banks (Chiaramonte and Casu, 2017). This happens when the liquidity premium required on rate of return on bank shares declines such that the reduction encourages banks to raise additional equity [2].

3. Methodology

3.1 Model and method

To examine the role of market structure and regulatory quality in determining bank capital ratio, we follow studies such as Anginer et al. (2018), Liu et al. (2013) and Schaeck and Cihak (2012) and model bank capital as a function of competition, a set of bank-specific and macroeconomic and institutional variables as presented in Eqn (1).

(1)γi,t= β0+ β1 γi,t1+ β2 ψi,t+ β3χi,t+β4κi,t+μi+ηt+εi,t
where γ is the capital ratio for bank i, at period t, and γi,t1 is one period lagged bank capital. The measures for competition/market structure is captured by ψ. χ is a vector of bank-specific variables and κ captures macroeconomic and institutional variables. μi is time-invariant unobservable bank-specific effect, ηt is time-specific effect common to all banks but changes through time, εi,t is the time-varying error term, β0β4  are coefficients estimates. Table 1 provides a description of the variables in Eqn 1.

We use the two-step Sys-GMM of Blundell and Bond (2000), an instrumental variable technique, over other methods such as the generalised least squares method to address potential endogeneity between capital ratio (γ) and competition (ψ) which may arise due to reverse causality in Eqn (1). The method in addition takes into account serial correlation between the lagged dependent variable (γi,t1) and other variables in the regression model [3]. Furthermore, the Sys-GMM controls for unobserved heterogeneity and considers the issue of unit roots in the macroeconomic data (Binder et al., 2005). The Sys-GMM is preferred over the difference GMM because it reduces potential bias in finite samples and yields more consistent coefficient estimates (Roodman, 2009). We report important test statistics such as the Arellano and Bond AR (1), AR (2) and the Hansen test to validate the use of the Sys-GMM estimator. While the AR (1) and AR (2) checks for the absence of first- and second-order serial correlation in differenced residuals of the model, Hansen test checks for overidentifying restrictions and nonexistence of correlation between the error term and instruments used in the model with a null of valid instruments. It is equally important to note that Eqn (1) is a partial adjustment model that accounts for adjustment costs which arises when banks try to adjust to meet capital requirements. High adjustment costs may prevent banks from instantaneous change in capital when they fall short of regulatory requirements, making them liable to penalties (Brei and Gambacorta, 2016; Etudaiye-Muhtar et al., 2017; Ozili, 2015). To avoid this situation, banks would need to increase the capital ratio, and a positive and significant coefficient of the lagged capital ratio would indicate the presence of adjustment costs.

3.2 Data

Eqn (1) and method described in Section 3.1 is used to analyse bank-specific and country-level data obtained from Bankscope and World Bank Development Indicators for the period 2000 to 2016. Number of banks in the sample is driven by data availability [4]. We follow Punt and Van Rooij (2003) and use only publicly listed commercial banks because the observed group is homogenous and allows for better estimates. To remove duplicate bank-specific information, data are collected from consolidated statements in Bankscope, while macroeconomic and institutional quality data are from World Bank database for the same period. We include banks with at least three years of observations only following the procedures of Etudaiye-Muhtar et al. (2017) and Vithessonthi (2014) in anticipation of a small sample size and to guard against small cross-sectional variations. We address the potential effect of outliers in the data by employing a robust regression estimation technique to estimate regression coefficients following the technique of Frank and Goyal (2009) and Verardi and Croux (2009) [5]. Our final sample size consists of an unbalanced panel of 79 banks from 24 countries (see Appendix 1).

3.3 Discussion of variables

Our main independent variables of interest are market structure and institutional quality. We use bank-specific and macroeconomic variables that have been established by literature to affect bank capital as control variables. Table 1 presents a summary of variable description and source.

3.3.1 Market structure and institutional quality

Our variable for market structure is based on the credit market model developed by Allen et al. (2011), where bank capital changes due to creditors' behaviour in the credit market rather than regulatory requirements. In the model, market forces make banks hold capital levels well above the required amount even though it may be costly for them to do so. Competition is seen to encourage banks to hold higher capital levels because it signifies commitment to entice and monitor creditworthy customers. Furthermore, market structure and profits are two factors necessary to maintain financial stability. For instance, Otero et al. (2017, 2019) both show that market power drives performance in banks in the MENA region (a developing region with similar characteristics with banks in the present study). This suggests that such banks, upon earning more profits, build up their capital ratio to indicate financial stability and entice creditworthy customers. This position is in line with the assertion of Schaeck and Cihak (2012) that a bank becomes attractive to borrowers if its capital is observable because of the higher level of capital, which improves its ability to attract good credit and suggests a positive coefficient for bank competition. Nonetheless, studies also show that the existence of the too-big-to-fail syndrome (especially in situations where there are a few large banks) encourages banks to hold less capital, a situation explained by the moral hazard issue (De Jonghe and Öztekin, 2015; Schaeck and Cihak, 2012). Based on these arguments, we use bank concentration ratio and Lerner index as our variable for market structure following Otero et al. (2017, 2019) who also used two indicators for bank competition. Although several measures are available to capture market structure, our choice of these two variables is due to their availability for banks in the sample [6]. Higher values of bank concentration imply a less competitive market, while that of Lerner index suggests a more competitive market. Regulatory quality, which measures the perception of the ability of government to formulate and implement sound policies and regulations that promote private sector development (banking sector inclusive), is our proxy for institutional quality. This takes a value between −2.5 and 2.5 as obtained from World Development Governance Indicators (WGI) provided by Kaufmann et al. (2011). Higher values of this variable indicate higher quality of regulation and formulation, and we expect a positive effect on bank capital.

3.3.2 Bank-specific variables (profitability, risk, liquidity and bank size)

In terms of profitability, higher profit levels enable banks to increase their capital ratios to protect themselves against possible liquidation and signal positive information to the market about bank value (Etudaiye-Muhtar et al., 2017; Rime, 2001). This suggest a positive relationship with bank capital, which is consistent with the pecking order theory and for regions with less developed financial markets such as the ones in this study (Alraheb et al., 2019). We use the return on assets as our measure for bank profitability. Risk is another important factor that banks consider when determining the level of capital to hold (Schaeck and Cihak, 2012). For example, risk-based capital standards such as the Basel Committee Accord may destabilise a bank's capital ratio and the bank would need to readjust. In addition, banks may engage in excessive risk-taking to improve its earnings, and therefore the capital ratio (Vithessonthi, 2014). In this paper, we proxy risk with the ratio of loan loss reserves to gross loan and expect a positive association with bank capital. Bank liquidity measures a bank's financial strength because it acts as a buffer for distress and bank runs. Nonetheless, there has to be a balance between liquidity and bank capital in order to prevent a situation where liquidity affects bank capital negatively (Vithessonthi, 2014). These two positions imply that the effect of liquidity on bank capital is unclear. Our proxy for liquidity is the ratio of liquid assets to total assets. Relating to size, larger-sized banks have incentives such as lower costs of capital that enable them obtain additional capital and prevent taking on excessive risk (Konishi and Yasuda, 2004). Additionally, to maintain good ratings, large banks would need to have capital in excess of market-determined reserves (Jackson et al., 2002). Consequently, we expect bank size to have a positive coefficient. Size is measured at the natural logarithm of total assets.

3.3.3 Macroeconomic variables

Macroeconomic variables affect bank capital ratios mainly in two ways: procyclical or countercyclical, depending on business cycle fluctuations (Brei and Gambacorta, 2016; Durafe and Jha, 2018). During an economic boom, banks tend to increase their capital ratio to benefit from potential investment opportunities/take advantage of increased credit activities (Durafe and Jha, 2018; Schaeck and Cihak, 2012). Furthermore, banks may decide to use an expansionary monetary policy regime to increase capital ratios (Laeven and Majoni, 2003). Nevertheless, a thriving economy also implies a lower loan default rate, so banks do not necessarily need to increase capital ratio and may decide to lower the ratio (Ayuso et al., 2004; Brei and Gambacorta, 2016). We use the growth rate of real GDP to capture the effect of business cycles on bank capital. We also include inflation as a control variable because literature establishes a negative relationship between inflation and bank capital. For instance, Hortlund (2005) argues that inflation increases bank debt, leading to a reduction in bank capital. This situation continues until leverage-induced increasing returns are sufficient to hold them at constant levels. Inflation is measured as annual percentage of consumer price index. In terms of financial market development, a re-balancing of the capital ratio of banks is possible when there is positive development in financial markets. Leaning on the finance-growth theory, banks would take advantage of lower costs of funding attributable to development of the markets, thus obtaining additional capital at minimal cost (Bena and Ondko, 2012; Levine, 2005). However, financial liberalisation may also have the opposite effect, that is, lower bank capital. This occurs usually in markets where information asymmetries and excessive risk-taking by banks exist and mostly in markets where efficient supervision is not available (González and González, 2014; Vithessonthi, 2014). In this type of market, efficient supervision is also absent. The two different positions imply that the expected relationship between bank capital and financial market development is ambiguous. We use the ratio of domestic credit to the private sector by commercial banks to GDP as our proxy for financial market development.

4. Empirical results

4.1 Descriptive statistics and correlation

Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics of variables outlined in Table 1. The average values of the main variables of interest, that is, Lerner index and bank concentration are 0.309 and 53.408, respectively. For bank concentration, approximately 53% of total bank assets are held by the three largest banks, implying a less competitive market. Nonetheless, the Lerner index of 0.309 shows a competitive market, implying that high concentration does not necessarily translate to high market power. This is in line with the position of Leon (2014) that the different measures used to capture competition do not give the same interpretation, that is, do not give the same inferences. Regulatory quality has a mean of 0.455, with a maximum of 0.836 buttressing the low quality of regulation in the system.

The correlation matrix in Table 3 shows that the variables generally have low correlations, implying that multicollinearity is not an issue. Most variables are seen to have values less than 0.5, with the only exception being bank concentration and Lerner index. However, this is not a problem since the two market structure variables do not enter the regression equation at the same time. Bank capital is negatively correlated with bank concentration, while it has a positive correlation with Lerner Index with values of −0.254 and 0.097, respectively. However, without controlling for other variables that affect bank capital, it would be inappropriate to make inferences on the nature of the relationship between market structure and bank capital using correlation matrix. Consequently, we run Eqn (1) using the two-step Sys-GMM, an instrumental variable technique as outlined in the method section.

4.2 Regression estimates (market structure, regulatory quality and bank capital)

In Table 4, we report the results obtained from Eqn (1) in columns 1 for bank concentration, and in 2 for Lerner index. The dependent variable in both columns is bank capital. The two market structure variables have different coefficient signs and statistical significance in line with the assertion of Leon (2014) and inferences made from the descriptive statistics and correlation matrix.

The coefficient for bank concentration is negative and statistically significant (−0.035, p < 0.01) in column 1. This suggests that the less competitive nature of banks in the study, as noted in the descriptive statistics, leads to a lower bank capital ratio. The result is consistent with the assertions of Schaeck and Cihak (2012) and Uhde and Heimeshoff (2009) that banks tend to hold higher capital ratios when operating in competitive environments and conversely for banks in less competitive settings. From the moral hazard view, the too-big-to-fail syndrome that encourages banks to hold less capital may be applicable to the banks in this study given that 53.408% of the total assets are held by the three largest banks in the study (see Table 2). Regulatory authorities view them as too big to fail and would put in place measures to prevent such from happening (Mishkin, 1999). The Lerner index, although positive, has a non-significant effect on bank capital, implying that market power does not have any influence on capital ratio. Liu et al. (2013) and Alraheb et al. (2019) found similar results for banks in 10 European countries and the MENA region, respectively. The different results obtained from the two variables further affirm Leon (2014) that they do not necessarily give the same inference. Overall, the results show that bank concentration is a more important determinant of bank capital for this study than the Lerner index, which is more of a measure of pricing market power (Leon, 2014). The institutional variable represented by regulatory quality shows a negative and statistically significant coefficient in both columns (−0.022, p < 0.01; and −0.100, p < 0.01), suggesting that bank capital reduces with improvement in the quality of regulation. It is possible that with stronger regulatory quality, banks would have no need to engage in excessive risk activities, necessitating an increase in capital ratio (Ozili, 2018; Vithessonthi, 2014).

Taken together, the two variables (competition and institutional quality) suggest that high regulatory quality in less competitive markets dissuades banks from engaging in excessive risk-taking activities that would necessitate holding capital ratio in excess of regulatory requirements. In addition, the concentrated market may increase the information asymmetry problem common in less developed financial markets. This makes it difficult for banks to monitor and screen borrowers, and they would be unable to differentiate between high- and low-quality debtors (Ariss, 2010). However, while a high regulatory quality may be sustained, there is a need to encourage healthy competition that can lead to an increase in bank capital because a reduced capital ratio may affect bank stability.

In line with the pecking order theory, the results show positive and statistically significant coefficients for bank profitability in both columns (0.647, p < 0.01; 0.885, p < 0.01), implying that banks increase their capital ratios following improved earnings to guide against unforeseen circumstances (Alraheb et al., 2019). Consistent with Konishi and Yasuda (2004) and Jackson et al. (2002), the coefficients of bank size in columns 1 and 2 are positive and statistically significant (0.514, p < 0.01; 0.323, p < 0.001, respectively), suggesting that large-sized banks benefit from economies of scale when raising additional capital. In addition, large banks would need to have capital in excess of market-determined reserve order to maintain good credit ratings, thus the positive coefficients. Although bank liquidity serves as a buffer to prevent bank runs, the results in Table 4 (column 1) for bank concentration show an inverse relationship between liquidity and bank capital (−0.017, p < 0.1), indicating that more liquid banks would have lower capital ratios. A bank that is highly liquid does not necessarily need to have excess capital ratios because the risk of a bank run is low (Vithessonthi, 2014).

The sign and level of significance of gross domestic product coefficient in the Lerner index column (−0.089, p < 0.01) implies that the variable is countercyclical, inferring that in a booming economy, there is lower probability of loan default; thus, there is no need for banks to increase capital ratio and may decide to lower the ratio, in line with the arguments of Ayuso et al. (2004) and Brei and Gambacorta (2016). Inflation has negative and statistically significant coefficients in both columns (−0.048, p < 0.01; −0.073, p < 0.01), consistent with the argument of Hortlund (2005) that it increases bank debt leading to a reduction in bank capital. This situation remains until leverage-induced increasing returns are sufficient to hold them at constant levels. We do not find support for either the finance-growth or financial liberalisation theory, because the coefficient for financial market development is insignificant in both columns.

To validate the results in Table 4, we report p-values of F-statistics, AR (2), Hansen and lagged bank capital. The significance of F-statistics at 1% significance level in the two columns implies the joint significance of all variables in explaining bank capital. The non-significance of AR (2) shows the absence of serial correlation in differenced residuals, while that of Hansen indicates that the instruments used are valid and the model is not over-identified. Furthermore, the positive and significant coefficients for the lagged bank capital justify the use of a dynamic model and the presence of adjustment costs that may hinder a bank from instantaneous change in capital ratio, consistent with earlier arguments of Brei and Gambacorta (2016), Ozili (2015) and Etudaiye-Muhtar et al. (2017).

4.3 Indirect effect of market structure and regulatory quality on bank capital

In the preceding section, we investigated the direct effect of market structure and institutional quality on bank capital ratio. In this section, we interact the two variables to determine their indirect effect and test the hypothesis that strong institutions and healthy competition existing side by side should encourage banks to hold capital in excess of what is required by regulatory authorities. To do this, we remodify Eqn (2) to include an interactive term (market structure*regulatory quality), and the results are presented in Table 5.

(2)γi,t= β0+ β1 γi,t1+ β2 ψi,t + β3χi,t+β4κi,t+β5 δi,t+μi+ηt+εi,t
where δi,t represents the interaction of market structure and competition for bank i at period t. All other variables remain as defined in Table 1. Results from Eqn (2) are presented in Table 5.

The coefficient for the interaction term in Table 5 is negative and statistically significant in column 1 (−0.001, p < 0.01), suggesting that the direct effect on bank capital by market structure and regulatory quality is accentuated when the two variables exist alongside each other. This provides support for the results presented in Table 4 that high regulatory quality in less competitive markets dissuades banks from engaging in excessive risk-taking activities that would necessitate holding capital ratio in excess of regulatory requirements. Column 2 for Lerner index has an interactive term that is not significant. Furthermore, we observe that signs and significance of coefficients of control variables in the regression equation are not qualitatively different from what was reported in Table 4.

5. Conclusion

Given the developing nature of the African financial system, this paper empirically investigates the nexus between market structure, institutional quality and bank capital ratio for a sample of 79 banks in 24 African countries for the period 2000–2016. The descriptive statistics suggests that the banking sector is concentrated and non-competitive. Controlling for endogeneity and autocorrelation, the regression results show that concentration and regulatory quality lowers bank capital ratio. Consistent with prior studies on less developed financial systems, our results imply that regulatory quality in less competitive markets (our sample) lowers bank capital, an indication that banks in such markets are dissuaded from engaging in excessive risk-taking activities that would necessitate holding capital ratio in excess of regulatory requirements. Our results have important policy implications for regulatory authorities and bank management. While improved regulatory quality should be maintained, banks should be encouraged to engage in healthy competition to improve the intermediation process. This would motivate banks to hold capital ratios appropriate for their level of banking activities and not engage in excessive risk-taking activities that would erode capital. Noting that our sample is taken from publicly listed commercial banks, further research may investigate and compare results from non-listed banks to determine if there is any difference in findings between the two categories.

Variable description and sources

S/NVariableDescriptionSource
1.Bank capitalRatio of equity to total assets (%)Bankscope
2.Lerner indexDifference between output prices and marginal costs (relative to prices) and is calculated as PMCP  where P is the price of banking outputs and MC is marginal costs. Higher values of the Lerner index indicate less bank competition (%)World Bank Global Financial Development Report
3.Bank concentrationTotal assets held by 3 largest banks of a country to the total assets of all banks in the country (%)World Bank Global Financial Development Report
4.Bank profitabilityReturn on assets and is calculated as the ratio of a bank's net income to its average assets (%)Bankscope
5.Credit riskRatio of loan loss reserves to gross loan (%)Bankscope
6.Bank liquidityRatio of liquid assets to total assets (%)Bankscope
7.Bank sizeNatural logarithm of bank total assetsBankscope
8.Gross domestic productYear on year growth rate of real GDP (%)World Bank development
Indicators database
9.InflationInflation based on annual consumer price index (%)World Bank development
Indicators database
10.Financial market developmentRatio of domestic credit to the private sector by commercial
banks to GDP (%)
World Bank development
Indicators database
11.Regulatory qualityPerception of the ability of government to formulate and implement sound policies and regulations that promote private sector development. Takes a value between −2.5 and 2.5World Bank governance
Indicators database

Note(s): Table 1 shows the description and source of variables employed in the study. Values of the Lerner index are extracted from the Global Financial Development Report of the World Bank

Descriptive statistics

VariableMeanStandard deviationMinimumMaximum
Bank capital11.6475.912−4.2183.21
Bank concentration53.40814.94332.521100
Lerner index0.3090.093−0.0840.459
Bank profitability1.9441.667−9.927.36
Credit risk6.0115.8980.1945.16
Bank liquidity24.90127.7840.3581.6
Bank size5.4440.9753.556.436
Gross domestic product4.3112.973−2414.047
Inflation7.2955.304−1.08636.908
Financial market development45.74534.8037.137160.125
Regulatory quality0.4550.1440.0040.836

Source(s): Bank-level and country-level data as outlined in the data section

Correlation matrix

Variables1234567891011
(1)Bank capital1.000
(2)Lerner index0.097**1
(3)Bank concentration−0.254*−0.603***1
(4)Bank profitability0.361*0.0480.0441
(5)Credit risk−0.0490.198***−0.243***−0.325***1
(6)Bank liquidity0.424−0.0430.0440.019−0.0161
(7)Bank size0.073**−0.0630.058−0.122**−0.081*0.077*1
(8)Gross domestic product0.117**0.026−0.136***0.185***−0.0570.038−0.083**1
(9)Inflation0.231***−0.071−0.0150.329***0.0390.180***−0.045−0.0151
(10)Financial market development−0.272***−0.095***0.304***−0.334***−0.047−0.119***0.177***−0.279***−0.279***1
(11)Regulatory quality−0.191***0.0570.290***0.010−0.204***−0.024−0.039−0.136***−0.312***0.447***1

Note(s): *, ** and *** represents 1%, 5% and 10% significant levels, respectively

Regression estimates

12
Bank capital(t-1)0.654*** (0.024)0.121*** (0.013)
Bank concentration−0.035*** (0.006)
Lerner index2.612 (1.606)
Bank profitability0.647*** (0.036)0.885*** (0.142)
Credit risk0.023 (0.017)0.018 (0.043)
Bank liquidity−0.017* (0.009)−0.014 (0.028)
Bank size0.514*** (0.144)0.323*** (0.118)
Gross domestic product−0.017 (0.010)−0.089*** (0.032)
Inflation−0.048*** (0.009)−0.073*** (0.021)
Financial market development0.001 (0.003)0.006 (0.010
Regulatory quality−0.022*** (0.006)−0.100*** (0.020)
F-statistics p-value0.0000.000
Time dummyYesYes
AR (1) p-value0.0270.063
AR (2) p-value0.6350.348
Hansen p-value0.4450.314
Number of banks7979

Note(s): Table 4 reports coefficient estimates of Eqn (1), with small sample adjustment and corrected standard errors in parenthesis using the two-step system GMM technique. Dependent variable in both columns is bank capital. Variables are as defined in Table 1. Columns 1 and 2 present results when bank concentration and Lerner index are used as measures of market structure, respectively. *** and * refer to 1% and 10% level of significance, respectively. The insignificance of AR (2) indicates the absence of second-order serial correlation in first-differenced errors. The p-value of Hansen is also insignificant, implying that instruments are valid and are not overidentified

Interaction effects (competition regulatory quality)

12
Bank capital(t-1)0.654*** (0.013)0.473*** (0.083)
Bank concentration−0.164*** (0.012)
Lerner index−14.543 (10.663)
Bank profitability0.629*** (0.043)0.998*** (0.174)
Credit risk−0.003 (0.018)0.039 (0.048)
Bank liquidity−0.017** (0.008)−0.022 (0.029)
Bank size0.327*** (0.086)0.428** (0.169)
Gross domestic product−0.032*** (0.007)−0.113*** (0.036)
Inflation−0.051*** (0.008)−0.072*** (0.025
Financial market development0.003 (0.003)0.013 (0.011)
Regulatory quality−0.038** (0.019)−0.182*** (0.054)
Market structure*regulatory quality−0.001*** (0.000)0.339 (0.217)
F-statistics p-value0.0000.000
Time dummyYesYes
AR (1) p-value0.0100.023
AR (2) p-value0.7360.483
Hansen p-value0.2480.363
Number of banks7979

Note(s): Table 5 reports coefficient estimates of Eqn (2), with small sample adjustment and corrected standard errors in parenthesis using the two-step system GMM technique. Dependent variable in both columns is bank capital. Variables are as defined in Table 1. Columns 1 and 2 present results when bank concentration and Lerner index are used as measures of market structure, respectively. *** and ** refer to 1% and 10% level of significance, respectively. The insignificance of AR (2) indicates the absence of second-order serial correlation in first-differenced errors. The p-value of Hansen is also insignificant, implying that instruments are valid and are not overidentified

S/NCountrySample no.
1.Botswana3
2.Burkina Faso1
3.Cote d'Ivoire4
4.Egypt7
5.Gambia1
6.Ghana5
7.Kenya7
8.Libya1
9.Malawi3
10.Morocco5
11.Mozambique1
12.Namibia1
13.Niger1
14.Nigeria8
15.Republic of Benin1
16.Rwanda2
17.Senegal1
18.South Africa8
19.Sudan1
20.Tanzania4
21.Tunisia8
22.Uganda2
23.Zambia1
24.Zimbabwe3

Notes

1.

Market structure in this study relates to how competitive the banking sector is. We use the two terms interchangeably.

2.

Liquidity premium reduces when the share of funds invested in cash and near-cash equivalents increase, thereby reducing bank liquidity risk.

3.

See Roodman (2009) for a detailed explanation of the method.

4.

Anginer et al. (2018) also stopped in 2016 because data from Bankscope database were discontinued in January 2017. In terms of data availability, Boateng et al. (2018) used a similar approach.

5.

Econometrics literature also establishes that GMM is robust with respect to heteroskedasticity and non-normality of data (e.g. Antoniou et al., 2008)

6.

In using these two variables, we take note of the view of Leon (2014) that although the two variables are measures used to capture competition, they may not give the same interpretation that is,. do not give the same inferences.

Appendix 1The countries and sample banks in each country for the study are as below

References

Allen, F., Carletti, E. and Marquez, R. (2011), “Credit market competition and capital regulation”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 983-1018.

Allen, F., Carletti, E., Cull, R., Qian, J., Senbet, L. and Valenzuela, P. (2012), “Resolving the African financial development gap: cross-country comparisons and a within-country study of Kenya”, Working Paper No. 18013, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, .

Alraheb, T.H., Nicolas, C. and Tarazi, A. (2019), “Institutional environment and bank capital ratios”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 43, pp. 1-24.

Anginer, D., Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Mare, D.S. (2018), “Bank capital, institutional environment and systemic stability”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 37, pp. 97-106.

Antoniou, A., Guney, Y. and Paudyal, K. (2008), “The determinants of capital structure: capital market-oriented vs bank-oriented institutions”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 43 No. 1, pp. 59-92.

Ariss, R.T. (2010), “On the implications of market power in banking: evidence from developing countries”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 765-775.

Ayuso, J., Pérez, D. and Saurina, J. (2004), “Are capital buffers pro-cyclical?: evidence from Spanish panel data”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 249-264.

Beck, T. and Cull, R. (2013), “Banking in Africa”, Working Paper No. 6684, World Bank Policy Research, World Bank.

Bena, J. and Ondko, P. (2012), “Financial development and the allocation of external finance”, Journal of Empirical Finance, Vol. 19, pp. 1-25.

Berger, A.N. (1995), “The relationship between capital and earnings in banking”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 432-456.

Berger, A.N., Herring, R.J. and Szegö, G.P. (1995), “The role of capital in financial institutions”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 19 Nos 3-4, pp. 393-430.

Binder, M., Hsiao, C. and Pesaran, M.H. (2005), “Estimation and inference in short panel vector autoregressions with unit roots and cointegration”, Econometric Theory, Vol. 21 No. 4, pp. 795-837.

Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (2000), “GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions”, Econometric Reviews, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 321-340.

Boateng, A., Asongu, S., Akamavi, R. and Tchamyou, V. (2018), “Information asymmetry and market power in the African banking industry”, Journal of Multinational Financial Management, Vol. 44, pp. 69-83.

Brei, M. and Gambacorta, L. (2016), “Are bank capital ratios pro-cyclical? new evidence and perspectives”, Economic Policy, Vol. 31 No. 86, pp. 357-403.

Calomiris, C.W. and Jaremski, M. (2016), “Deposit insurance: theories and facts”, Annual Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 8, pp. 97-120.

Chiaramonte, L. and Casu, B. (2017), “Capital and liquidity ratios and financial distress. Evidence from the European banking industry”, The British Accounting Review, Vol. 49 No. 2, pp. 138-161.

De Jonghe, O. and Öztekin, Ö. (2015), “Bank capital management: international evidence”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 154-177.

Demsetz, R.S., Saidenberg, M.R. and Strahan, P.E. (1996), “Banks with something to lose: the disciplinary role of franchise value”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review of Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 1-14.

Durafe, A. and Jha, A. (2018), “Bank capital buffer, bank credit and economic growth: evidence from India”, Afro-Asian Journal of Finance and Accounting, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 257-270.

Etudaiye-Muhtar, O.F., Ahmad, R., Olaniyi, T.A. and Abdulmumin, B.A. (2017), “Financial market development and bank capitalization ratio: evidence from developing countries”, Paradigm, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 126-138.

Flamini, V., Schumacher, M.L. and McDonald, M.C.A. (2009), “The determinants of commercial bank profitability in Sub-Saharan Africa”, Working Paper WP/09/15, International Monetary Fund, 01 January.

Francis, M.E. (2013), “Determinants of commercial bank profitability in sub-Saharan Africa”, International Journal of Economics and Finance, Vol. 5 No. 9, pp. 134-147.

Frank, M.Z. and Goyal, V.K. (2009), “Capital structure decisions: which factors are reliably important?”, Financial Management, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 1-37.

González, V.M. and González, F. (2014), “Banking liberalization and firms' debt structure: international evidence”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 29, pp. 466-482.

Hortlund, P. (2005), “The long-term relationship between capital and earnings in banking”, Working Paper No. 611, SSE/EFI working paper series in Economics and Finance.

Jackson, P., Perraudin, W. and Saporta, V. (2002), “Regulatory and ‘economic’ solvency standards for internationally active banks”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 26 No. 5, pp. 953-976.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M. (2011), “The worldwide governance indicators: methodology and analytical issues”, Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, Vol. 3, pp. 220-246.

Keeley, M.C. (1990), “Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 80 No. 5, pp. 1183-1200.

Konishi, M. and Yasuda, Y. (2004), “Factors affecting bank risk taking: evidence from Japan”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 28 No. 1, pp. 215-232.

Laeven, L. and Majoni, G. (2003), “Loan loss provisioning and economic slowdowns: too much, too late?”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 12 No. 2, pp. 178-197.

Laeven, L., Ratnovski, L. and Tong, H. (2016), “Bank size, capital, and systemic risk: some international evidence”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 69 No. 1, pp. S25-S34.

Leon, F. (2014), “Measuring competition in banking: a critical review of methods”, Working paper No. 201412, CERDI.

Levine, R. (2005), “Finance and growth: theory and evidence”, in Philippe, A. and Steven, D. (Eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier, The Netherlands, pp. 865-934.

Liu, H., Molyneux, P. and Wilson, J.O. (2013), “Competition and stability in European banking: a regional analysis”, The Manchester School, Vol. 81 No. 2, pp. 176-201.

Milne, A. (2002), “Bank capital regulation as an incentive mechanism: implications for portfolio choice”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 26, pp. 1-23.

Mishkin, F.S. (1999), “Lessons from the Asian crisis”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 709-723.

Oduor, J., Ngoka, K. and Odongo, M. (2017), “Capital requirement, bank competition and stability in Africa”, Review of Development Finance, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 45-51.

Otero, L., Razia, A., Vivel, M. and Lado, R. (2017), “Competition, concentration and risk taking in banking sector of MENA countries”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 42, pp. 591-604.

Otero, L., Razia, A., Vivel, M. and Lado-Sestayo, R. (2019), “Market structure, performance, and efficiency: evidence from the MENA banking sector”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 64, pp. 84-101.

Ozili, P.K. (2015), “Determinants of bank profitability and Basel capital regulation: empirical evidence from Nigeria”, Research Journal of Finance and Accounting, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 124-131.

Ozili, P.K. (2018), “Banking stability determinants in Africa”, International Journal of Managerial Finance, Vol. 14 No. 4, pp. 462-483.

Punt, L.W. and Van Rooij, M. (2003), “The profit-structure relationship and mergers in the European banking industry: an empirical assessment”, Kredit und Kapital, Vol. 36 No. 1, pp. 1-29.

Rime, B. (2001), “Capital requirements and bank behaviour: empirical evidence for Switzerland”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 25 No. 4, pp. 789-805.

Roodman, D. (2009), “A note on the theme of too many instruments”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and statistics, Vol. 71 No. 1, pp. 135-158.

Schaeck, K. and Cihak, M. (2012), “Banking competition and capital ratios”, European Financial Management, Vol. 18 No. 5, pp. 836-866.

Uhde, A. and Heimeshoff, U. (2009), “Consolidation in banking and financial stability in Europe: empirical evidence”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 33 No. 7, pp. 1299-1311.

Verardi, V. and Croux, C. (2009), “Robust regression in Stata”, Stata Journal, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 439-453.

Vithessonthi, C. (2014), “The effect of financial market development on bank risk: evidence from Southeast Asian countries”, International Review of Financial Analysis, Vol. 35, pp. 249-260.

Further reading

Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998), “Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 87 No. 1, pp. 115-143.

Chronopoulos, D.K., Liu, H., McMillan, F.J. and Wilson, J.O. (2015), “The dynamics of US bank profitability”, The European Journal of Finance, Vol. 21 No. 5, pp. 426-443.

Corresponding author

Oyebola Fatima Etudaiye-Muhtar can be contacted at: etudaiye.mf@unilorin.edu.ng

Related articles