Metrics to improve universal-service fund disbursements

Rohan Samarajiva (LIRNEasia, Colombo, Sri Lanka)
Gayani Hurulle (LIRNEasia, Colombo, Sri Lanka)

Digital Policy, Regulation and Governance

ISSN: 2398-5038

Article publication date: 11 October 2018

Issue publication date: 6 March 2019

1936

Abstract

Purpose

Many governments wishing to provide telecommunication services to those who are unconnected have chosen the Universal Service Fund (USF) as the principal policy instrument. However, there is evidence that monies directly or indirectly collected from users of telecommunication services are lying unspent in these funds. The purpose of this paper is to propose metrics for measuring the disbursement efficacy of funds across time and across countries as an essential element of improving the performance of the universal service funds.

Design/methodology/approach

This paper proposes two metrics, the total disbursement rate (TDR) and the year-on-year disbursement rate (YDR), which can be used to assess the disbursement efficacy of universal service programs. It illustrates the value of the metrics by applying them to the USFs of India, Malaysia and Pakistan.

Findings

A move to push out funds has been observed in India in recent years. Pakistan had not reached the same momentum up to mid-2014. An improvement in Malaysia’s disbursement efficacy was observed until 2013, with nearly all of the funds collected in the previous year being disbursed. A significant proportion of the funds collected are lying unspent in the three USFs, nevertheless.

Originality/value

The proposed metrics are robust, objective and parsimonious indicators that allow comparison over time and across countries. They will enable productive, evidence-based conversations that will hold fund administrators accountable and will inform the design and implementation of more effective policy mechanisms.

Keywords

Citation

Samarajiva, R. and Hurulle, G. (2019), "Metrics to improve universal-service fund disbursements", Digital Policy, Regulation and Governance, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 102-114. https://doi.org/10.1108/DPRG-07-2018-0035

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Rohan Samarajiva and Gayani Hurulle.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

As is the case in all infrastructure industries, the telecommunications industry is affected by the challenge of serving all persons desirous of service. The normal incentives in infrastructure industries cause the suppliers, who tend to have varying degrees of market power, to prioritize the high-revenue, low-cost market segments. Governments, because of the nature of infrastructure services, tend to want suppliers to provide services sooner to a larger area or to a larger population than the suppliers may consider commercially viable. When the industry is monopolistic, service extension will occur because of government or extra-market pressure. With greater competition, there will be incentives for market forces to be more effective, but even then, some areas and populations perceived as likely to yield inadequate revenues in relation to costs may remain unserved.

Prior to the present wave of reforms, telecom services in most countries were provided by government-owned monopolies. These monopoly operators were regularly ordered to serve rural areas and regularly failed to comply with the possible exceptions of Australia and Finland. In the case of private monopolies, as in the USA, parts of Canada and the Philippines, the most common mechanism was a requirement in the operator license or concession contract that defined network deployment requirements, also known as universal service obligations (USOs). Other approaches included special franchises for rural areas and subsidies for rural areas.

The ICT Regulation Toolkit refers to universal access as a condition wherein everyone can access the service anywhere, at a public place; thus, it is also called public, community or shared access. Universal service, on the other hand, describes the situation wherein every individual or household can have service, using it privately, either at home or increasingly through wireless devices carried on the person (InfoDev & International Telecommunications Union, n.d.).

By around 2000, expert consensus converged on the stance that universal service/access funds were more effective than USOs for achieving the public-policy objective of extending service to rural areas, especially under conditions of workable competition (Clark, 1940). Indeed, the Regulation Reference Paper that was part of the Protocol Four of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) included specific provisions related to universal service that amounted to a legal obligation on the part of committing governments:

Any Member has the right to define the kind of universal service obligation it wishes to maintain. Such obligations will not be regarded as anti-competitive per se, provided they are administered in a transparent, non-discriminatory and competitively neutral manner and are not more burdensome than necessary for the kind of universal service defined by the Member. (World Trade Organization, 1996)

Debates around telecom-sector reforms also contributed to changes in the approach to extending coverage. Opponents of reform, primarily the managers and employees of state monopolies, made a two-fold argument. They argued that the new, private entrants would engage in “cream skimming,” or just serving the lucrative urban areas and/or commercial enterprises (Madden, 2010). They also attributed all the shortcomings of the now-threatened government-owned incumbent operator to its universal-service obligations, conveniently keeping silent about the poor performance in actually fulfilling those obligations.

In countries such as Malaysia and South Africa, universal-service obligations were imposed on the privatized incumbents (Gillwald, 2005). But in subsequent reforms, the policy shifted to the inclusion of provisions for universal service levies to be charged usually as a percentage of adjusted gross revenues (AGR). The funds so collected were to be expended on expanding universal service and access. This article seeks to assess the efficacy of this second generation of universal-service policies.

Universal service programs may be examined in terms of inputs, outputs and outcomes. The money going in, from whatever source, is inputs. Outputs are the activities for which the funds are applied. Outcomes of an effective universal-service policy would be the number of people connected as a direct result of universal-service subsidy programs, who would not otherwise be connected through market mechanisms. Outputs must precede the production of outcomes. The outputs of universal-service programs may be seen in terms of necessary and sufficient conditions. The necessary condition is that the money, once collected, must be disbursed from the fund. The sufficient condition is that the disbursed funds must be spent as intended by the enabling legislation or regulations. Unless the necessary condition of money being disbursed is satisfied, the sufficient condition of the disbursed funds being spent as intended by the enabling legislation or regulations cannot be examined. Without outputs, it is not possible to assess outcomes.

The outcome of an effective universal-service policy would be the number of people connected as a direct result of universal-service subsidy programs, who would not otherwise be connected through market mechanisms. An example would be the use of payphones that were provided to rural areas as a result of the Chilean universal-service auctions by inhabitants of the rural areas (Serra, 2000).

Additional taxes imposed on a particular good or service reduce demand (Musgrave and Musgrave, 1989). Thus, levies or taxes that are directly charged to end users or the service suppliers depress demand. In a market with adequate levels of competition, reduction of such levies is likely to reduce prices and increase demand. One defense of these kinds of levies is that they are similar to fuel taxes that help maintain highways.

In the case of bundled road taxes, the beneficiaries are the people who pay for the fuel. This is not the case with universal-service taxes in the telecom sector, except in the indirect and partial sense of the payees benefiting from the increased calling opportunities afforded by the addition of new customers to the network. But, in any case, there can be no benefit when fuel taxes are not used for road maintenance but are kept by government, which is the case with telecom taxes.

Inputs and the necessary condition for outputs can be measured in objective, quantitative terms. Being dependent on country-specific legislation and policies, the necessary condition for outputs and outcomes cannot be assessed in purely quantitative terms that can be compared across countries. They are also open to contestation.

Robust, objective and parsimonious indicators that allow comparison over time and across countries will assist stakeholders and policymakers design and implement effective policy mechanisms. The use of standardized, comparable indicators for USFs may allow not only administrators to ascertain their performance but also stakeholders to push them to take remedial action if the metrics show the status quo to be unsatisfactory.

This article proposes a set of metrics that can be used to assess the efficacy of universal service instruments, with emphasis on the necessary condition. It illustrates the value of the metrics by applying them to the Universal Service Funds (USFs) of India, Malaysia and Pakistan.

2. Literature review

Navas-Sabater et al. (2002) presented a heuristic for thinking about the relationship between sector reforms and subsidies, showing the need to differentiate between the market efficiency gap and the access gap in the design of universal-service programs (Figure 1).

The market-efficiency gap is best addressed by market reforms. The access gap refers to people and places that remain beyond the limits of the market because of inadequate income levels or its skewed distribution. Bridging the access gap requires subsidies to encourage service providers to enter these areas (De Silva, 2008). Others, such as Crandall et al. (2004), are less optimistic, stating that subsidies should not generally be used to promote universal service, and are likely to hurt the average consumer. The value of the heuristic proposed by Navas-Sabater et al. is diminished by its lack of a rule defining where the market-efficiency gap ends and the access gap begins. It does not preclude subsidies being implemented as solutions for problems better addressed by market mechanisms.

The World Bank was a major proponent and funder of USFs. Thus, it was highly significant when the Independent Evaluation Group of the World Bank, after reviewing 10 years of bank activities in the information and communication technology (ICT) sector stated, “targeted efforts to increase access beyond what was commercially viable have been largely unsuccessful. Support to universal access programs was largely superseded by the rollout of phone services by the private sector […]” (Independent Evaluation Group, 2011). In other words, market liberalization connected people. Subsidy programs did not.

The funding sources for USFs, for both telecommunications and others, such as the postal service, have been well documented (Cremer et al., 2001; Borsenberger et al., 2010). Despite many talking about how the preferable source of funds is the central budget as seen in Chile (Wellenius, 2000), most funds rely on levies collected through operators. The contradiction of trying to encourage the greatest use of telecom services (the stated objective of universal service) and imposing additional service-specific taxes on the same services did not attract much attention, with a few exceptions such as Crandall et al. (2004) and Samarajiva (2010).

Efficiency is given prominence in writing on the universal policy schemes in the USA. An example is the 2008 proposal to enact a Universal Service Reform Accountability and Efficiency Act of 2000 was intended to reform the collection and distribution of universal service support, which did not make it out of committee (Congressional Research Service, 2011). The literature on the US universal service programs focuses on inefficiencies, in the form of high administrative costs and misuse of funds, rather than on problems of disbursing money. The E-rate program, signed into law in the USA in the 1990s, sought to help schools and libraries gain access to telecommunications services. It has, however, faced some allegations of fraud and waste (Meer, 2006). It is noteworthy that such studies focus on the efficiency of individual projects, rather than on the utilization of all the funds in the USF.

From a more global perspective, the International Telecommunications Union (2013) refers to large amounts of undistributed funds, attributing this, in many instances, to the absence of access-gap evaluations and meaningful demographic surveys. A study by Ladcomm Corporation (2013) for GSMA, focused on disbursements, documenting the gap between the contributions gathered and the funds actually disbursed. Over US$1.1bn was left to be disbursed in the 64 countries studied.

There is a growing body of evidence showing that metrics can help drive governments drive reform processes. For example, the Sri Lankan government set up eight task forces based on the ten pillars of the World Bank’s Doing Business Index, with the aim of moving up 40 positions in the index within three years (Razak, 2018). This has been explored in the case of USFs in Goldstein (2009), who used data on unused funds published by the Universal Service Administrative Company in their quarterly reports, to measure the percentage of committed funds disbursed. The findings indicate that although the proportion of disbursed funds fell at first, the amount of undisbursed funding in expired grant accounts declined when concerted efforts were made to address the problem (Goldstein, 2009).

This paper proposes two metrics to allow for the disbursement of funds to be measured: the first is the total disbursement rate (TDR). The second is a year-on-year disbursement rate (YDR). Poor performance as documented by these indicators may cause USF administrators to step up the disbursement of the funds if projects that suit the objectives of the relevant USFs have been formulated, or plan to step down the collection of funds if suitable projects do not exist.

3. Methodology

3.1 Development of metrics

The first step is that of developing an easy-to-understand indicator that will permit the disbursement rate to be compared across time and across countries. This combines the two objective measures of inflows of funds (input) and outflows of subsidies (the necessary condition of output) over defined periods.

Two disbursement rates are proposed: the TDR and the YDR:

Totaldisbursementratet=(disbursementoffundst/fundsaccumulatedinUSFt1)*100

This measures the rate at which funds have been spent from the USF, relative to the funds accumulated in the fund at the beginning of the relevant period, which is set at a year. It is the rate of outflow of funds in a given year, relative to the previous year’s year-end balance. The flow of funds into the USF in the given year is not taken into consideration in the calculation to accommodate procedural delays such as those in India, where the money first goes into the consolidated fund before being transferred to the USF. The proposed TDR permits a reasonable time for the fund administrators to process the inflows.

The YDR is even more forgiving:

Yearonyeardisbursementratet=(disbursementoffundst/inflowoffundst1)*100

The YDR is the rate of outflow of funds in a given year relative to the inflow in the immediately preceding year. Funds that have accumulated in the USF over time are excluded from consideration. The YDR describes the efficacy of the agency in disbursing the most recently collected funds. Accumulated balances may not have been caused by those currently administering the funds, or been affected by actions outside their control, such as difficulties in obtaining funds kept with the Finance Ministry. In instances where significant accumulated balances exist, agencies should strive to achieve YDRs higher than 100 per cent. Otherwise, the TDR will continue to decline, even if the YDR is at acceptable levels. Excuses may be given for low TDRs. Because a high YDR is easier to achieve, poor performance is more difficult to justify.

3.2 Selection of case studies

The case studies are intended to illustrate the workings and the resulting efficiency of differently sized and structured funds. Three universal-service programs in Asia, with varied administrative structures, funding sources and levies and procedures to disburse funds, were chosen for this purpose. Additionally, the three countries varied demographically and economically. India’s population of 1.3 billion is over 36 times larger than Malaysia’s and nearly seven times as large as Pakistan’s (World Bank, 2018). Malaysia is an upper-middle-income country, while India and Pakistan are lower-middle-income countries.

The data for the paper were sourced primarily from the latest information available online on the websites of the USFs and regulatory bodies. Requests were made to obtain data on the inflows and disbursements in the Pakistani case.

3.2.1 Administrative structure.

The Indian Universal Service Obligation Fund (USOF) is administered as a separate administrative organization set up within the Department of Telecommunications, with The Indian Telegraph (Amendment) Act (2003) of stating that the Central Government is responsible for the coordination and timely utilization of the funds in the USOF.

The Malaysian Communications and Multimedia Commission (MCMC), the regulatory agency, manages the Malaysian Universal Service Provision Fund (USPF). In Pakistan, the USF is overseen by the Ministry of Information Technology but is administered by the independent and fully state-owned Universal Service Fund Guarantee Company Limited (USFGC). According to the USF policy, its operation must be technologically neutral unless circumstances require otherwise.

3.2.2 Funding sources.

The analyzed USFs receive inflows of funds through operators, which means that they actually come from current consumers. When taxes are itemized on customers’ bills and simply collected and transmitted to governments, it is clear who the payer is. The operator in this instance is simply the government’s tax collector. When levies and taxes are imposed on companies, they do not appear on the bills in itemized form. But they are little different from itemized levies and taxes. The company considers the mandatory levies or taxes as costs, no different from payments made to electricity companies or other suppliers. The business cases for offering services and making investments take into account the mandatory taxes or levies. The returns on investment are calculated based on the cost structure that includes the taxes or levies and the level of competition that determines the prices that can be charged. In addition to keeping prices above where they could be in the absence of levies or taxes and thus reducing quantity supplied, such levies or taxes also depress certain kinds of investments (Samarajiva, 2010).

In India, 5 per cent of the AGR is levied from all telecommunications service providers, except those who provide pure value added services such as internet, voice mail and e-mail services. An operator is deemed to be a universal service provider if it has a valid license or registration/authorization from the Central Government to provide telecom services or infrastructure. By law, funds may come into the USOF through another mechanism, through grants and loans made by the Central Government. This, however, has not occurred to date.

Malaysia, on the other hand, has determined a minimum revenue threshold. Regulation 27 of the USP Regulations only requires licensees whose net revenue derived from the designated services for the previous calendar year exceeded the minimum threshold of RM 2m (US$0.61m) to contribute 6 per cent of their weighted net revenue to the USPF. The Communications and Multimedia Act (Universal Service Provision) (Amendment) Regulations 2003 brought international calls, international roaming services, internet protocol telephony and Integrated Services Digital Network (ISDN), among others, within the calculation of the net weighted revenue. Services such as local and national calls, operator assisted calls and internet access charges are excluded when calculating weighted net revenue for this purpose [Communications and Multimedia Act, 1998: Communications and Multimedia (Universal Service Provision) (Amendment) Regulations, 2003].

While India and Malaysia have among the highest universal-service tax rates, at 5 and 6 per cent, respectively, licensees in Pakistan must pay a USF charge of up to 1.5 per cent of gross revenues minus inter-operator payments and related authority/Frequency Allocation Board mandated payments as determined by the Government in Pakistan. Access promotion charges may also be an alternative source of funding.

3.2.3 Modalities of disbursing funds.

In India, any funds received by the fund are first credited to the Consolidated Fund. They are then disbursed by Parliamentary appropriation [The Indian Telegraph (Amendment) Act, (2003). No. 8 of 2004]. Malik and De Silva (2005) state that giving statutory status to the USOF helped expedite disbursements. In Pakistan too, the USF Amendment Rules of 2013 provide for funds to be kept in the Federal Consolidated Fund and for the Ministry of Finance to release the funds in accordance with the procedures laid down by the Rules through budgetary mechanisms.

In Malaysia, funds from the USP Fund are disbursed to the designated service providers after claims are made upon the approval from the MCMC, the telecommunications regulator.

4. Disbursement efficacy

This section analyzes the collections and disbursements of the three funds to ascertain the efficacy of disbursement. TDRs and YDRs, as described in Section 3 above, are calculated for this purpose[1]. The performance of individual countries is first measured, after which cross-country comparisons are made.

4.1 Disbursement rates by country-individual performance

4.1.1 India.

Figure 2 shows that the inflow of funds to the USOF through Universal Access Levy (UAL) collections grew at a compounded annual growth rate of 10.1 per cent between 2002-2003 and 2017-2018. The increase is caused by growth of top-line revenues of operators in the early periods. While the disbursement of funds has fluctuated, it has constantly been lower than the inflows[2]. In total, 42 per cent of accumulated funds were disbursed in 2004-2005, but that high point has not been matched since. Disbursements picked up in 2016-2017, with the YDR reaching a record high of 75 per cent in 2017-2018.

4.1.2 Malaysia.

Disbursements in the first five years of operation were extremely low at US$8.9m, a mere 4.3 per cent of the inflows, being disbursed annually on average (Figure 3). Disbursements increased in 2008, but dropped to US$13.6m once again in 2009.

Disbursements came close to matching prior-year contributions in 2012 and 2013 yielding YDRs of 98 and 99 per cent, respectively. The YDR nearly halved in 2014, but rose to 79 per cent in 2015. It is noteworthy that the funds disbursed in 2016 exceeded funds collected that year.

The accumulation of funds over the years prevented the TDR from exceeding 25 per cent in 2012 and 2013. Funds with accumulated balances must achieve YDRs higher than 100 per cent for several years if they are to improve overall disbursement efficacy as depicted by the TDR. Only Malaysia has come close to achieving that.

4.1.3 Pakistan.

Figure 4 shows variations in the inflow of funds into the USF. The highest recorded inflow was in 2009-2010, after which contributions decreased and rose once again. The inflows in 2014-2015 were lower than in the previous year. Usually, contributions to the USF increase year on year, driven by increased operator revenues.

Almost 30 per cent of the funds in the Pakistan USF at the beginning of 2008-2009 were disbursed within the next year. However, the disbursement rate has seen a general downward trend since then. The most recent data indicates that only a fifth of the total inflows are disbursed. Despite the disbursed funds almost doubling (173 percent) between 2012-2013 and 2013-2014, the TDR only increased by 2.1 per cent. The YDR remained stable at 35 per cent for the past two years. Contrary to perception, the Pakistan USF has never been strong in disbursing funds.

4.2 Disbursement rates by country: comparative assessment of performance

Despite admitting the limitations of other USF programs, the World Bank’s Independent Evaluation Group (2011) portrays the Pakistan’s USFGC as a success, which is surprising. Tables I and II allow for the performance of the three USFs to be compared with each other over time. Some countries have been more successful than others in pushing out the collected funds. Malaysia, for example, in 2012 and 2013, managed to disburse nearly all the funds it collected in the previous year. India too managed to increase disbursements with both its TDR and YDR more than doubling in between 2015-2016 and 2016-2017. The absence of data for Pakistan beyond 2013-2014 prevents the authors from making statements regarding its performance since 2014. Its TDR and YDR in both 2012-2013 and 2013-2014 were superior to that of India in the same years, though well below that of Malaysia.

5. Policy implications

Universal service schemes in most countries are failing. Money is being extracted from current consumers of telecommunication services and is lying fallow in government accounts.

The poor disbursement performance of a universal service scheme that is portrayed as exemplary, the Pakistan USFGC (Independent Evaluation Group, 2011), illustrates the seriousness of the problem. This highlights the need to go beyond anecdote to develop proper metrics and issue regular reports that are available to the public. It is only by comparing performance across time and among countries that proper assessments can be made and remedial action taken.

Quarterly or annual public reporting of the type mandated by the FCC (Goldstein, 2009) is required, ideally using common metrics. This would hopefully lead to questions being raised in the media and in the legislatures. Ideally, the basic information on inflows, outflows and outputs will be made publicly available by fund administrators and perhaps even the YDRs and TDRs published at regular intervals. Regional organizations or think tanks may compile comparative indicators and perhaps even conduct independent assessments of outcomes and outputs. Where Right to Information laws exist, they may be used to obtain the required data.

Remedial actions may include systematic evaluations by national governments or by the funds themselves or by stakeholders and independent think tanks to identify the causes of poor disbursement and overall efficacy of outputs, including whether the money was spent according to program objectives. Obviously, action may have to be taken to improve the administration of the funds. Here, those best positioned to act are within the country and not at the regional or international levels. Given a steady and substantial inflow of funds, there is little excuse for not being able to effectively disburse the money.

The General Agreement on Trade in Services imposes a legal obligation on Members who have committed to the Regulation Reference Paper to ensure that the USO programs they wish to maintain “are administered in a transparent, nondiscriminatory and competitively neutral manner and are not more burdensome than necessary for the kind of universal service defined by the Member” (World Trade Organization, 1996). In the event of a Member invoking GATS dispute-resolution provisions in relation to the above, data on low YDRs and TDRs may support a claim that the impugned USO program is more burdensome than necessary, because it collects far too much money than can be spent to serve the stated objectives.

Levies based on fixed percentages of an ever-increasing base will result in inflows into the USF that will increase year-on-year. The case studies show this occurs, with only a few exceptions. If the objective is the closing of an identified gap and the actions taken by the USF are contributing to its closing, it is difficult to envisage the need for ever-increasing resources over time. The optimal solution would be a program that is based on the identification of the gap that has to be bridged or the task that has to be achieved, along with a clear description of the desired end state. This could, for example, be that all human settlements above a certain population threshold be provided with wireless coverage.

The case studies show the goal posts have been changed over time. For example, in India, the focus has shifted from the provision of village public telephones to fiber optic cable in the “middle mile.” This could be interpreted as mission creep by the uncharitable or as sensible adjustments necessary in a rapidly changing ICT industry by others.

Even in a sub-optimal solution, there is little justification for a universal-service program that is flooded with ever-increasing funds simply as a result of industry growth. To a great extent, the difficulties of disbursement experienced by all USFs could be attributed to increasing inflows.

One way to control this problem would be to build in automatic step-downs in the percentage (e.g. the Indian levy could be stepped down from the current five per cent by half a percentage point every year). Another solution would be to automatically activate reductions when the TDR goes below a defined threshold. A third solution would be to build in emergency brakes, so that collections cease at specified levels of TDR. The advantage in the first solution is that it can be factored into the business plans of the operators and would thus be helpful in terms of the budget telecom network business model explicated by Samarajiva (2010). Unpredictable windfalls that would result from the second or third solutions cannot be built into business plans. Thus, they are likely to benefit the shareholders of the operators rather than customers or the policy objectives of greater connectivity.

Once enormous balances have accumulated, there is little alternative but to come up with grandiose spending schemes such as BharatNet (formerly known as the National Optical Fibre Network) (Srinivasan and Ilavarasan, 2015), which accounted for 77 percent of the Indian USOF’s disbursements in 2016-2017. This is a sub-optimal solution, but one that is difficult to avoid once massive balances have been built up. Preventing accumulation is thus an important element of effective universal-service policy. Metrics that will help keep track of disbursement efficiency and of accumulation, as proposed in this article, are thus essential for the formulation of good universal-service policy and for their effective implementation.

Figures

Conceptual access gap framework

Figure 1

Conceptual access gap framework

Status of Indian USOF

Figure 2

Status of Indian USOF

Status of Malaysian USPF

Figure 3

Status of Malaysian USPF

Status of Pakistan USF

Figure 4

Status of Pakistan USF

Comparative TDRs (%)

India (FY April-March) Malaysia (FY January-December) Pakistan (FY July-June)
Year TDR Year TDR Year TDR
2003-2004 15.57 2003
2004-2005 40.84 2004 2.94
2005-2006 32.96 2005 3.45 2005-2006, 2006-2007, 2007-2008 Not calculable, because of lack of data by year
2006-2007 21.31 2006 1.22
2007-2008 15.53 2007 2.32
2008-2009 10.32 2008 4.46 2008-2009 29.12
2009-2010 13.46 2009 1.02 2009-2010 17.82
2010-2011 15.55 2010 5.39 2010-2011 12.38
2011-2012 6.72 2011 14.95 2011-2012 3.23
2012-2013 1.93 2012 20.61 2012-2013 4.33
2013-2014 5.60 2013 20.71 2013-2014 6.41
2014-2015 5.07 2014 10.19
2015-2016 6.28 2015 15.33
2016-2017 13.34 2016 15.12
2017-2018 13.19

Source: Calculated by authors

Comparative YDRs (%)

India (FY April-March) Malaysia (FY Jan-December) Pakistan (FY July-June)
Year YDR Year YDR Year YDR
2003-2004 12.74 2003
2004-2005 62.82 2004 2.90
2005-2006 51.85 2005 8.68 2005-2006, 2006-2007, 2007-2008 Not calculable, because of lack of data by year
2006-2007 45.66 2006 3.39
2007-2008 36.78 2007 7.90
2008-2009 25.66 2008 17.68 2008-2009 27.79
2009-2010 42.35 2009 4.46 2009-2010 25.94
2010-2011 55.81 2010 29.09 2010-2011 19.47
2011-2012 26.11 2011 77.91 2011-2012 8.86
2012-2013 8.27 2012 98.66 2012-2013 35.24
2013-2014 29.00 2013 98.37 2013-2014 35.08
2014-2015 26.11 2014 48.14
2015-2016 38.41 2015 78.66
2016-2017 71.66 2016 67.87
2017-2018 74.75

Source: Calculated by authors

Notes

1.

The calculations are made in the local currency, and then converted to USD at the average exchange rate of the relevant period for comparability.

2.

The reimbursements of license fees and spectrum charges (to BSNL) were not taken into consideration when calculating the disbursement rates. They were merely accounting allocations; the USOF states that the negative fund balance was only notional.

References

Borsenberger, C., Cremer, H.D., Donder, P., Joram, D. and Roy, B. (2010), “Funding the cost of universal service in a liberalized postal sector”, in Crew, M.A. and Kliendorfer, P.R. (Eds) Heightening Competition in the Postal and Delivery Sector, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 220-234.

Clark, J.M. (1940), “Toward a concept of workable competition”, American Economic Review, Vol. 30 No. 2, pp. 241-256.

Communications and Multimedia Act (1998), Communications and Multimedia (Universal Service Provision) (Amendment) Regulations (2003), Malaysia, available at https://digitalcommons.law.byu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1215&context=elj (accessed 15 July 2018).

Congressional Research Service (2011), “Universal service fund: background and options for reform”, available at: www.everycrsreport.com/reports/RL33979.html (accessed 15 July 2018).

Crandall, R.W., Hahn, R., Litan, R.E. and Wallsten, S. (2004), “Bandwidth for the people, brookings institute”, available at: www.brookings.edu/research/bandwidth-for-the-people/ (accessed 15 July 2018).

Cremer, H., Gasmi, F., Grimaud, A. and Laffont, J.J. (2001), “Universal service: an economic perspective”, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, Vol. 72 No. 1, pp. 5-43.

De Silva, H. (2008), “The dumbing-down of smart subsidies”, in Samarajiva, R. and Zainudeen, A. (Eds), ICT Infrastructure in Emerging Asia: Policy and Regulatory Roadblocks, IDRC, Canada and Sage Publications, Ottawa, New Delhi, pp. 191-215.

Gillwald, A. (2005), “Good intentions, poor outcomes: telecommunications reform in South Africa”, Telecommunications Policy, Vol. 29 No. 7, pp. 469-491.

Goldstein, M.L. (2009), Telecommunications: Long-Term Strategic Vision Would Help Ensure Targeting E-Rate Funds to Highest Priority Users, United States Government Accountability Office, available at: www.gao.gov/assets/290/287867.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

Iftikhar, P. (2015), “Summary of USF inflows”, Unpublished Dataset.

Independent Evaluation Group (2011), Capturing Technology for Development: An Evaluation of World Bank Group Activities in Information and Communication Technologies, World Bank. Washington, DC, available at: http://ieg.worldbankgroup.org/sites/default/files/Data/Evaluation/files/ict_evaluation.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

InfoDev & International Telecommunications Union (n.d.), “Module 4: universal access and service”, ICT Regulation Toolkit, available at: www.ictregulationtoolkit.org/toolkit/4 (accessed 15 July 2018).

International Telecommunications Union (2013), Universal Service Fund and Digital Inclusion For All Study. ITU, available at: www.itu.int/en/ITU-D/Conferences/GSR/Documents/ITU%20USF%20Final%20Report.pdf (accessed 22 July 2018).

Ladcomm Corporation (2013), Survey of Universal Service Funds: Key Findings, GSMA, available at: www.gsma.com/publicpolicy/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/GSMA2013_Report_SurveyOfUniversalServiceFunds_KeyFindings.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

Madden, G. (2010), “Economic welfare and universal service”, Telecommunications Policy, Vol. 34 Nos 1/2, pp. 110-116.

Malaysia Communications and Multimedia Commission (2014), Universal Service Provision Annual Report 2013, MCMC, available at: www.skmm.gov.my/skmmgovmy/media/General/pdf/USP-AR-2013.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

Malaysia Communications and Multimedia Commission (2017), Universal Service Provision Annual Report 2016, MCMC, available at: www.skmm.gov.my/skmmgovmy/media/General/pdf/MCMC_USP_Report_BI_2016.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

Malik, P. and De Silva, H. (2005), “Diversifying network participation: study of India’s universal service instruments”, presented at WDR Dialogue Theme 3rd cycle, available at: http://lirneasia.net/2005/11/study-of-indian-universal-service-instruments/ (accessed 15 July 2018).

Meer, J. (2006), “Highway robbery online: is E-rate worth the fraud?”, Brigham Young University Education and Law Journal, Vol. 2006 No. 1, pp. 323-356.

Musgrave, R.A. and Musgrave, P.B. (1989), Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th ed., McGraw-Hill.

Navas-Sabater, J., Dymond, A. and Juntunen, N. (2002), “Telecommunications and information services for the poor: towards a strategy for universal access”, World Bank discussion paper [432], World Bank, Washington, DC.

Razak, A. (2018), “Sri Lanka aims 20-notch leap in next world bank rankings”, Sunday Observer, 7 January.

Samarajiva, R. (2010), “Leveraging the budget telecom network business model to bring broadband to the people”, Information Technology and International Development, Vol. 6, pp. 93-97.

Serra, P. (2000), “Subsidies in Chilean public utilities”, Policy Research Working Paper [WPS2445], World Bank, Washington, DC.

Srinivasan, N. and Ilavarasan, P. (2015), “White elephant or a game changer? An analysis of national optical fibre network of India”, Economic & Political Weekly, Vol. 50 No. 42.

The Indian Telegraph (Amendment) Act (2003), No. 8 of 2004, India, available at: http://usof.gov.in/usof-cms/miscellaneous/Indian%20Telegraph%20Act%202003.PDF (accessed 15 July 2018).

The Indian Telegraph Amendment Bill No. 46 of (2006), available at: http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/APCITY/UNPAN025618.pdf (accessed 15 July 2018).

Universal Service Fund Policy (Final) (2018), Pakistan, available at: https://usf.org.pk/assets/rules-pdf/usf-policy.pdf (accessed 16 July 2018).

Universal Service Obligation Fund (2018a), “History”, available at: www.usof.gov.in/usof-cms/usof-history.jsp (accessed 16 July 2018).

Universal Service Obligation Fund (2018b), “Fund status in table”, available at: www.usof.gov.in/usof-cms/usof-fund-status-table.jsp (accessed 16 July 2018).

Wellenius, B. (2000), “Extending telecommunications beyond the market: toward universal service in competitive markets”, Viewpoint [206], World Bank.

World Bank (2018), “Population, total”, World Bank Databank, available at https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.TOTL (accessed 15 July 2018).

World Bank (2018), “World bank country and lending groups”, available at https://datahelpdesk.worldbank.org/knowledgebase/articles/906519-world-bank-country-and-lending-groups (accessed 15 July 2018).

World Trade Organization (1996), Regulation Reference Paper, Annex to the Fourth Protocol to the GATS Agreement, the “Agreement on Basic Telecommunications”.

Acknowledgements

This work was carried out with financial support from the UK Government’s Department for International Development and the International Development Research Centre, Canada. The views expressed in this work are those of the creators and do not necessarily represent those of the UK Government’s Department for International Development and the International Development Research Centre, Canada. The authors wish to thank Parvez Iftikhar, former CEO of the Universal Service Fund of Pakistan, Payal Malik, Advisor to the Competition Commission of India/Senior Research Fellow at LIRNEasia and Nur Sulyna Abdullah, Chief Officer of Corporate Strategy at the Malaysian Communication and Multimedia Commission, for their input on the USFs of their respective countries. Thecomments received from those present at the internal review at LIRNEasia, and two anonymous reviewers at CPRsouth are also much appreciated.

Corresponding author

Gayani Hurulle can be contacted at: gayanih@gmail.com

About the authors

Rohan Samarajiva is Chair at LIRNEasia, Colombo, Sri Lanka. He is founding Chair of LIRNEasia, a think tank active across emerging economies in South and South East Asia. He served as Director General of the Telecommunications Regulatory Commission of Sri Lanka and is currently Chair of the apex organization for ICT in the government of Sri Lanka. He was Associate Professor of Communication and Public Policy at the Ohio State University in the USA, Visiting Professor of Economics of Infrastructure at TU Delft in The Netherlands and Honorary Professor at the University of Moratuwa, Sri Lanka.

Gayani Hurulle is Research Manager at LIRNEasia, Colombo, Sri Lanka. He was a Research Manager at LIRNEasia at the time of conducting this research, where she led research projects on ICT accessibility for persons with disabilities, and online privacy and security. She also engaged in conducting multi-country nationally representative surveys on ICT use. She holds a BSc in Economics from the University of London with First Class (Hons) and is currently pursuing graduate education at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy at the National University of Singapore.

Related articles